In the course of the last week, the new Chancellor Philip
Hammond presented his Autumn Statement to parliament. As a general rule, this interim
report on the state of UK public finances is only of interest to those of us
who have an interest in fiscal policy issues. But this year, there was a lot
more interest as it provided us with the first view of how the Office for
Budget Responsibility –the fiscal watchdog – assessed the cost of Brexit, and
what sort of fiscal response the government was able to provide.
The main takeaways were that the economy will grow more
slowly than projected in March, when the exercise was last conducted, and that
both public deficits and debt will be higher in the medium-term. Moreover, the
government has amended its fiscal rules such that it must no longer achieve a budget
surplus in three years’ time, and it will be content with a falling debt-to-GDP
ratio over this horizon. The Institute for Fiscal Studies always provides a sober
analysis of UK fiscal issues (here) and for a short overview of their take, Director Paul Johnson’s introductory
remarks nail most of the issues (here).
The only area where I would disagree with the IFS is that the additional
capital spending goes nowhere near far enough to tackle the infrastructure spending
deficit which has been building for a number of years.
My own forecasts, which you can find in the Treasury’s
compendium of economic forecasts (here) have long suggested that official medium-term projections for public finance
consolidation have been overly optimistic. For one thing, I have generally come
up with slightly slower revenue projections than the OBR but more importantly, I
have never been convinced that the government would be able to hold to its eye-wateringly
tight spending assumptions. Two years ago, George Osborne’s plans implied that
the share of public spending in the economy would fall to its lowest since the
1930s – he quickly dropped that pledge as the 2015 election loomed.
Even though current plans do not appear anywhere near as
aggressive, they still imply a considerable amount of fiscal austerity. Whilst spending
on the National Health Service is ring-fenced (health is protected from the budgetary
cuts which hit other departments) this shifts the burden of spending cuts onto
other areas. Moreover, an ageing population is putting strains on the health
budget which the current fiscal plans do not address. So the quality of its service will deteriorate
without additional resources.
One of the great ironies of fiscal policy over the past six
years has been the extent to which it has hit hardest those at the lower end of
the income scale, since policy has focused on cutting the welfare budget which
has resulted in major curbs on welfare entitlement. Yet much of the evidence
suggests that the poorest households were much more likely to have voted for
Brexit than those higher up the income scale. Anger at the squeeze on incomes is
derived more from government policy than from the impact of EU migrants pushing
down earnings (in much the same way that high immigration was the result of policy
failures to curb non-EU migrant numbers, which still account for more than 50%
of the total).
Predictably,
of course, pro-Brexit MPs were quick to denigrate the fiscal outline presented
this week, particularly since the OBR attributes roughly half the deterioration
in public finance forecasts since March to the decision to leave the EU. Iain
Duncan Smith, said it was "another
utter doom and gloom scenario" by an organisation that “has been wrong in every single forecast
they've made so far." The walking cliché that is Jacob Rees-Mogg
argued it has made "lunatic"
assumptions and added that "experts,
soothsayers, astrologers are all in much the same category." Ironically,
as the FT pointed out yesterday (here),
one of the Chancellor’s measures to provide support to a particular stately
home directly benefits the Rees-Mogg family as it is the ancestral home of Jacob’s
mother-in-law. So perhaps we could restore a little order to the public
finances by removing that “lunatic” gesture?
More generally, I am beginning to find the Brexit brigade rather
more than tiresome. Their tactic is to denigrate those who dare question
whether Brexit is such a good idea. There will be longer-term economic
consequences – we should have little doubt about that. And since when in a democracy
has debate about the merit of an idea stopped just because we held a vote on
it? As former PM John Major noted recently, the referendum result was a close
call and “the tyranny of the majority has
never applied in a democracy and it should not apply in this particular
democracy.” He should know: Major had to suffer continued sniping from
those he called the “cabinet bastards” (his “only excuse is that it was true”)
In my view, a tight fiscal policy helped stir up resentment
at the status quo which morphed into the Brexit vote. Boris Johnson’s policy
may be to have cake and eat it too, but that is not how economics works in the
real world. Get used to it!
No comments:
Post a Comment