It is now three years since the British electorate narrowly
voted in favour of leaving the EU, and despite the best efforts of the government
the UK remains an EU member. The longer the saga drags on, the more vociferous
are the Brexiteers who believe they are being denied the victory that is
rightfully theirs. When David Cameron first mooted the idea of a referendum, it
was to lance the boil of Euroscepticism within the Conservative Party. This
strategy could not have been less successful if he had tried. Britain remains
more polarised than at any time in living memory and Brexit has consumed
politicians to such a degree that they have no time for anything else.
Historians argue that the 1956 Suez Crisis was a defining moment in British post-war history, yet three years after the
event the scars were at least beginning to heal. Not so with Brexit.
There has been a lot of revisionism over the past three
years, with Brexit supporting politicians making the case that people knew what
they were voting for and that “the will of the people” must be respected. The
argument is simple and convincing – and profoundly wrong. In the modern argot,
Brexiteers are engaging in heavy “gaslighting.” Admittedly David Cameron did
point out prior to the referendum that a vote for Brexit would be “to leave the EU and leave the single market.
We’d then have to negotiate a trade deal from outside with the European Union.”
But Brexit supporters reassured the electorate that the UK would retain access
to the single market (“absolutely nobody is talking about threatening our place in the single market”)
and the customs union was barely even mentioned. For anyone who doubts my take
on events, look at analysis conducted by the charity Full Fact.
The pamphlet sent to all households ahead of the referendum certainly
did not suggest that leaving the EU would mean leaving the single market let alone the customs union.
Instead, it pointed out that “Voting to
leave the EU would create years of uncertainty and potential economic
disruption … Some argue that we could strike a good deal quickly with the EU
because they want to keep access to our market. But the Government’s judgement
is that it would be much harder than that” (here is a link to the pamphlet
if you want to check for yourself).
Whatever Remainers and Leavers may disagree about, it is
indisputably the case that the difficulties inherent in leaving the EU were
clearly pointed out prior to the referendum. The events of the
past three years have borne out this assessment and it is the issue of leaving
the EU on terms that would not crash the economy that has always been at the
centre of my disagreement with those who wish to leave at any price.
Millionaires like Jacob Rees-Mogg or Boris Johnson may be able to survive the hit in the event of a no-deal Brexit but it will be
a lot harder for those far lower down the income scale. And for all the fact
that the apparent foot-dragging has been blamed on the Remainers in government
who have tried their best to thwart the project, the simple truth is that MPs
do have a duty to look out for the interests of their constituents, and these
will not be served by a no-deal Brexit.
Who will drive the car towards the cliff edge?
The next four months will be critical in this regard. It is has
long been assumed that Boris Johnson is a near-certainty to be chosen as the
next Tory party leader (his recent domestic issues notwithstanding).
However, the bookmakers put him at 1-6 odds-on compared to 1-16 on Friday,
whilst the odds against his challenger Jeremy Hunt have narrowed from 12-1 to
4-1. Neither candidate fills me with any confidence.
Johnson maintains that the EU would not have to levy tariffs
on UK imports in the event of a no-deal Brexit because the UK could rely on
Article 24 of GATT.
This is untrue. Article 24 only applies if an agreement has been reached, not
if it has been decided not to have an agreement or the two parties are unable
to come to an agreement. If the EU were to drop tariffs against the UK in the
event of no-deal, it would have to do so against all other countries under the WTO’s
Most Favoured Nation rules and that is not going to happen. Meanwhile Jeremy
Hunt said at a Tory leadership hustings event yesterday that he had “visited an amazing company … that employs about
350 people; their margins are around 4%. A 10% tariff would wipe them out. So
there would be an economic impact of no-deal. If that was the only way to
deliver Brexit then I’m afraid we have to do that because that’s what people have
voted for. We are a democracy first and foremost.” Yes folks, you read that
right. The party of business is prepared to throw small businesses under the
bus to deliver Brexit (check the link).
But assuming Johnson does get the gig, he will have a lot of
hard work to do. He will come into office on the back of a track record of
disloyalty during Theresa May’s tenure and a reputation as one of the worst
foreign secretaries ever to grace the post. He is widely distrusted at home
based on his famously loose relationship with the truth, and is even less
respected across Europe where he is regarded as the face of Brexit. Johnson has
insisted that the UK should leave the EU on 31 October: If he holds to that
pledge, it will be without any new deal with the EU which has said it will not
reopen negotiations, and certainly not with him. But parliament has already
expressed its opposition to a no-deal Brexit so if he pushes ahead with this
option MPs are unlikely to work with him on other issues (remember the
Conservatives form a minority government), which raises the prospect of a
general election.
One option that should not be ruled out is that Johnson may
be forced to put the Brexit question back to the electorate at some point when
it becomes clear that the EU is not prepared to negotiate and the alternative
is a hard Brexit. For one thing, it would spike the Labour Party’s attempts to
put a second referendum on the table, and if the Conservatives stand for
anything it is to keep Jeremy Corbyn out of 10 Downing Street. Nor is Johnson a
Brexit ideologue, like many on the lunatic fringe of his party, and he far more
ideologically flexible than Theresa May. If any politician can sell the idea of
a second referendum, it is him.
Whilst I would attach only a small probability to this
outcome, it is evident that as we head into a fourth year of political impasse,
something has got to give. Let us also not forget that the EU has been
remarkably tolerant of the UK’s position so far. We can debate whether the EU’s
stance is right but it has always been open to discussion. That might change in
future as senior positions at the European Commission come up for grabs.
Jean-Claude Juncker and Donald Tusk are about to ride off into the sunset and
their successors may wish to move the EU debate forward rather than having to
be tied up by Brexit. We know that President Macron is opposed to a further
Brexit extension, and he is unlikely to grant Johnson any favours.
A year ago, I refrained from offering any predictions as to
where we would be in the Brexit debate in June 2019, largely because I
suspected that an Article 50 extension would preserve the status quo. I do not
want to offer any hostages to fortune this time either. But I do not think we
will be in the same waiting room in 12 months’ time. In order to properly
confront the issue, the next prime minister will have to either risk crashing
the economy or going where Theresa May did not dare, by offering a referendum
or in an extreme case withdrawing the Article 50 notice. The time for talking
is over. We need to move on.
Sunday 23 June 2019
Thursday 20 June 2019
Strike whilst the fiscal iron is hot
Apart from a brief splurge in the immediate aftermath of the
financial crisis, western governments have generally adopted a tight fiscal
stance over the past decade with the result that it has been left to central
banks to do nearly all of the policy easing. In my last post, I noted that we
have broadly reached the limit of what monetary policy can be expected to
achieve and that during the next cyclical downturn fiscal policy will have to
play a much bigger role. This raises two questions: (i) how much impact will
fiscal easing have and (ii) how much fiscal room do governments have?
With regard to the first issue, the now accepted wisdom is
that fiscal multipliers are higher than expected prior to the last recession.
Much of the evidence available prior to the Great Recession suggested that
fiscal multipliers in the developed world were significantly less than unity.
In other words, a one percentage point fiscal injection produced a long-run
increase in output of less than 1%. If that is indeed the case, the economy
would be relatively unresponsive to a fiscal injection and the resultant
increase in debt could be judged to be too costly.
But four years after the crash, the IMF concluded that it
had underestimated fiscal multipliers by between 0.4 and 1.2. On the assumption
that the pre-recession average was around 0.5, the updated research suggests
that the true multipliers are in the range 0.9 to 1.7 which is a whole
different ball game. Furthermore, they concluded that the efficacy of fiscal
policy is greater when interest rates are at the lower bound, as they have been
for the past decade but which was never seriously considered prior to 2008 as
it was not an outcome that many people foresaw. However, on the basis of the latest
empirical evidence it appears that a fiscal expansion will deliver a decent
bang for the buck.
But can governments afford to expand fiscal policy when
government debt levels are already very high? Obviously, the current position
in which public debt levels across Europe average more than 80% of GDP is not a
great place to start. But an environment in which interest rates remain low has
created a significant degree of fiscal space for governments. The concept of
fiscal space is defined as how much governments can borrow without losing
market access or facing sustainability challenges. Conventional economic wisdom
suggests that markets will limit their purchases of sovereign debt if it is
rising at a rapid pace, and require compensation in the form of higher yields.
Higher yields raise the cost of debt servicing and increase outlays on interest
income which, if they cannot be offset by spending cuts in other areas, result
in higher deficits and debt. There is thus a dynamic link between interest
rates and debt. But in today’s environment interest rates are lower for any
given level of debt than we might have thought possible in the past, hence the
idea that fiscal space has increased.
The well-known solvency conditions for public debt depend on
the primary deficit (i.e. excluding debt servicing costs), the rate of nominal
GDP growth and the interest rate on debt (see chart). The higher the deficit or
interest rates the greater the upward pressure on debt-to-GDP ratios, whilst
the faster is GDP growth the more downward pressure there is. Getting the
balance of these factors right is an important consideration in fiscal
solvency, as it suggests it is possible to run a public deficit and still
broadly keep the debt ratio stable, depending on the extent to which GDP growth
exceeds the interest rate.
This growth/interest rate nexus thus becomes crucial. To
look at this in a long-term context I have taken data for the UK going back to
1700. During the 18th and 19th centuries on average, the
interest rate on debt was higher than the rate of GDP growth. Even though the
UK did run a primary surplus over the period, the debt ratio continued to creep
upwards from around 20% of GDP in 1700 to 200% by the end of Napoleonic Wars
and only fell back below 100% in 1861. On average during the 19th century
the debt ratio averaged 120%. But although the UK ran a primary deficit on
average during the 20th century, the rate of GDP growth exceeded the interest
rate with the result that the debt ratio tended to fall. Even though the debt
ratio hit almost 250% in the wake of the Second World War, a combination of
solid growth and financial repression which put a lid on interest rates, was
sufficient to produce a significant reduction in the debt ratio to just above 20%
by the early-1990s.
The takeaway is that high debt levels need not be the
obstacle to fiscal expansion that many politicians seem to think. Admittedly,
GDP growth has slowed over the last decade compared to what we were used to
prior to 2008, but even if trend real growth is in the range 1% to 1.5% and
inflation remains stuck at 1.5%, this implies nominal GDP growth of around 2.5%
to 3%. Meanwhile central banks are currently engaged in a policy of financial
repression (though they would never call it as such). Right now, 10-year yields
in the UK are just above 0.8% and in Germany they are well into negative
territory at -0.3%. Clearly, therefore, nominal GDP growth is higher than the
interest rate on debt and a quick calculation allows us to estimate the size
of the primary deficit that will allow the debt-to-GDP ratio to remain stable[1]. Current
figures for the UK, for example, suggest that a deficit of 1.9% is eminently sustainable.
To those politicians who argue that reducing the debt ratio is
an objective of itself, I pose the question why? The demand for long-term
government paper has never been higher as investors who are flush with the
liquidity created by central banks fall over themselves to find a place to
invest it. This is not to say that governments should be opening the taps with
no regard for the future. After all, if rates do rise the cost of servicing
high debt levels will also increase. But there is scope for a judicious
loosening of the reins, and there has never been a better time to use the
opportunity afforded by low interest rates for social purposes. Those European
governments who are passing up this opportunity (and not just those in the euro
zone) are guilty of sloppy economic analysis, and perhaps even more
egregiously, impoverishing their citizens for no good reason. Fiscal
opportunities like this have historically not come around often.
[1] Primary
deficit = (Debtt-1/ GDPt-1)*(1-(1+it)/(1+yt))
(assuming stock-flow adjustment equals zero)
Tuesday 18 June 2019
The limits of central banking
Prior to the great crash of 2008, investment bankers were –
at least in their own minds – regarded as masters of the universe. No more. As
their fancy clothes, woven from cloth so fine that the eye could not see it,
were revealed to be non-existent, they were usurped by central bankers who used
the muscle of zero interest rates and the power of their balance sheets to
rescue the global economy from meltdown. More than a decade later and questions
are increasingly being raised as to whether the tools which were deployed in
2009, and which are still in use today, are fit for purpose. Worse still,
central bankers can be forgiven for wondering whether they have been hung out
to dry by politicians who seem increasingly unwilling to provide the necessary
degree of support to allow them to do their job effectively.
The BoE: A relative oasis of calm
The BoE finds itself in a slightly easier position than
either the Fed or ECB although it has been sucked into the political fallout
from Brexit, and with a new Governor set to take over from Mark Carney in just
over seven months’ time, his successor may face an unenviable task in steering
a post-Brexit course. One criticism that can be levelled at the BoE is that its
forward guidance policy, which has often hinted at rate hikes which never
materialise, may be about to miss the mark again. Indeed, recent hints that the
next rate move will be upwards flies in the face of economic data, which point
at below-target inflation in H2, and trends in the global monetary cycle. In
common with many central banks, it has failed to create space to ease policy in
the event that the economy cools. Central bankers dismissed this line of
reasoning when conditions were propitious for a rate hike in 2014, and whilst
Brexit has complicated the picture, it is hard to avoid the feeling that the
BoE will go into the next economic slowdown with precious little ammunition.
The ECB: Taking flak from all sides
Across the channel, the ECB’s situation is even more
desperate. Despite having cut the main refinancing rate to zero and the deposit
rate to -0.4% whilst boosting its balance sheet to almost 40% of GDP, a
meaningful economic recovery in the euro zone remains elusive and inflation
continues to undershoot the ECB’s target. There are now expectations that the
ECB will counter current economic conditions with even more monetary easing – a view that Mario Draghi reinforced this morning.
The ECB is all that has stood between the integrity of the euro zone and
disaster: It has done all the policy easing whilst governments have stood idly
by without deploying any of the fiscal ammunition at their disposal. Draghi,
who will leave his post as ECB President in October, deserves great credit for
doing “whatever it takes” to keep the show on the road. Those who have
criticised Draghi, including Bundesbank President Weidmann and various northern
European politicians, should take some time to reflect on what might have
happened in 2012 had the ECB not opened the taps.
However, the criticisms levelled by Weidmann at least come
from someone with skin in the game. Draghi’s hints of further easing were met
today by a Twitter blast from the self-styled stable genius in the White House accusing the ECB of weakening the euro against the dollar “making it unfairly easier for them to compete against the USA. They
have been getting away with this for years, along with China and others.”
This sends two messages: (i) Trump is a lobster short of a clambake and more
seriously (ii) he threatens to open a new front in the war of economic
nationalism, dragging the euro zone into a conflict which has hitherto been
confined to the US and China.
The Fed: Managing in the presence of a stable genius
Imagine, therefore, what it must be like to be in Jay
Powell’s shoes. The Fed has done what the textbooks recommend by taking away
some of the excessive stimulus as the economy recovered. Unfortunately, Trump
has determined that the Fed is the main obstacle to the ongoing US upswing and
has been excoriating the FOMC for not cutting rates. Worse still, a story
surfaced today suggesting that in February the White House explored the possibility of stripping Powell of his chairmanship and leaving him as a Fed governor. This is
an unprecedented attack on the independence of the central bank. Not that
politicians have refrained from dictating to the Fed in the past. One story,
recounted by Reuters journalist Andy Bruce, recalls instructions from the White
House to former Fed Chairman Paul Volcker ordering him not to raise interest
rates during an election campaign. “Volcker,
knowing the command was illegal, left the room without saying anything.”
But the attacks on Powell are far worse – and lest we forget, he was appointed
by Trump in 2018 with the endorsement that “He’s
strong, he’s committed, he’s smart.”
The FOMC has recently revised down its assessment of the
need for future rate hikes and it is increasingly likely that the next move
will be a cut. It is not clear whether this is a direct response to the
President’s attacks or whether the Fed has misread the economic outlook so
badly that it feels the need to ease policy rather than tighten, as it believed
necessary at the start of the year. However, to the extent that the Fed may be
trying to head off further attempts by Trump to impose his own candidates on
the FOMC, following the failed attempts to appoint Stephen Moore and Herman Cain, it is likely that the Fed is acceding to the pressure. Perhaps the Fed’s view
is that by throwing a few small scraps in Trump’s direction, it will be better
placed to maintain its independence in the longer run. But whilst it has long
been evident that the Fed is not as free from political influence as it
portrays, selling out in such an obvious manner could have the reverse effect
by undermining its perception of independence in the market.
Dealing with the lower bound
The common themes across the central banking universe are that
they are running out of tools to deal with the low-inflation world which we
inhabit today, whilst also coming under much greater pressure to deliver on
politicians’ objectives. With regard to instruments at the central banks’
disposal once interest rates reach the lower bound, there are essentially just
three: QE, forward guidance and driving interest rates into negative territory
as the ECB has done. At a recent Fed monetary policy conference (a so-called “Fed Listens Event” which deserves more in-depth coverage another
time), a paper by Sims and Wu highlighted that QE is the most useful tool of the three; forward guidance
depends on a central bank’s credibility (cf. the Fed’s position) and that
negative rates become less effective the larger is the balance sheet (cf. the
ECB’s position).
With central banks having tried all of these instruments to
a greater or lesser degree, it is difficult to avoid the conclusion that we are
near the end of the road with regard to monetary policy. After all, central
banks have largely failed to stimulate inflation and there are serious concerns
that if the floodgates are opened even further, this will serve only to store
up greater problems in the future. Indeed, I have long argued that we will only know the full impact of low interest rates in the very long
term once we see what our pensions are worth. What this does suggest is that much
more of the burden of managing the economy will have to fall on fiscal policy in
future – an issue I will deal with in my next post. The good news is that this
will at least take central bankers out of the firing line and make politicians take
some responsibility for what they should have been doing all along.
Monday 17 June 2019
Not the end of history
It is thirty years since Francis Fukuyama’s essay “The End of History?” was published in the magazine The National Interest. It was
subsequently fleshed out into a book which elevated Fukuyama to the first rank of
commentators on global geopolitical issues. Viewed from the perspective of
three decades later, it is an idea that has not aged well. Fukuyama’s thesis
was that liberal democracy had achieved such dominance as a form of government
around the world that we had reached “the
end point of mankind's ideological evolution and the universalization of
Western liberal democracy as the final form of human government.” This was
pretentious hubris in 1989. Today, the argument just looks crass.
There is no doubt that the argument has been hugely
influential amongst western leaders. The likes of Bill Clinton and Tony Blair
went to great lengths to use foreign policy as a tool to promote western
values. The “end of history” mind-set also underpinned the development of the
EU. Following the fall of the Iron Curtain, the European Economic Community –
whose aim was to promote economic integration amongst its 12 member states –
opted to ratify the Maastricht Treaty to create the European Union thus marking
a further step on the road to creating an “ever closer union” between the
peoples of Europe. It also facilitated an eastward expansion to incorporate 16
new members, many of which had little recent experience of the forms of
government practiced in the west. Expansion was based on the idea that
membership is open to "any European
State which respects the values referred to in Article 2 and is committed to
promoting them." Those Article 2 values are "respect for human dignity, freedom, democracy, equality, the rule of
law and respect for human rights, including the rights of persons belonging to
minorities." Very Fukuyama-esque.
All seemed to be proceeding on track until the crash of
2008. Unfortunately, governments over-promised and under-delivered on what they
were able to do to stimulate a lasting economic recovery following the great
recession, thus paving the way for populists to make political headway and
helping to undermine Fukuyama’s ideas. But it is the rise of China that has had
a bigger impact on the post-1989 hubris. China can in no way be defined as a
liberal democracy, yet the performance of its economy has been the most
significant economic event since the dawn of the industrial revolution in the
eighteenth century. It would be a major stretch to assume that the majority of
Chinese would be prepared to swap their system of government for the rapid rise
in living standards experienced over the past three decades. An even more
extreme example is Russia where moves towards a more democratic system of
government coincided with a period of hardship which tilted the scales back
towards authoritarianism.
Fukuyama supporters would no doubt point out that there is a
distinction between “history” and ”events” where the former represents an
overall narrative and the latter are the individual occurrences which go up to
make the whole picture. But this is to overlook the fact that events can have a
significant impact on the overall course of history. Fukuyama’s thesis rests on
the notion that even if we deviate from the path of liberal democracy, it will
eventually reassert itself in the long run, but this is not particularly
helpful if we end up in a prolonged period of deviation from the “ideal” – as
those who lived through the period 1914 to 1945 might testify.
Fast forward to the present day and the takeaway is that
those who dismiss concerns regarding the behaviour of Donald Trump or the
fragmentation of European politics as a short-term problem may be missing the
point. Trump clearly has no interest in finding an accommodation with China on
trade issues and indeed has ratcheted up the pressure in recent months.
Tempting though it is to put this down to posturing ahead of the 2020 election,
it would be naïve in the extreme to expect him to change his position in his
second term as President (assuming he is re-elected). Rules-based liberal
democracy is not part of Trump’s makeup and even if he does prove to be an aberration
from the US presidential norm, he could do sufficient damage to Sino-US
relations in the interim that ends up inflicting significant long-term damage
on the US and undermining the cause of liberal democracy on both sides of the
Pacific.
In a similar vein, those expecting the current shenanigans
over Brexit to be resolved easily and quickly will also be disappointed. The
idea that “something will turn up” is a Micawberish way of thinking that does
not do justice to the magnitude of the problem. Too many politicians have
signed up to the Fukuyama view that politics will quickly tend towards the
liberal democratic norm. But the grand sweep of history suggests that societies
are often plunged into chaos by sudden and unexpected events which overwhelm
the system’s capacity to respond and a long period of adjustment then ensues.
In the case of Brexit, politicians cannot hide behind the excuse that a no-deal
Brexit is unexpected. Indeed, many of them have advocated it. But a generation
of politicians that has grown up without bad things happening because something
always turns up may be pushing their (and our) luck too far.
In my view, Fukuyama’s assertion of an end of history makes
the mistake of assuming history as some form of linear progression. Perhaps it
should be thought of as a 3D spiral, in which we appear to be making progress
in one dimension whilst going over the same old ground in another (see chart).
Or as Mark Twain (allegedly) said, “history doesn’t repeat itself but it often
rhymes” which is why we should wake up to the damage that Trump or a no-deal
Brexit might cause rather than assume it will quickly pass.
Monday 10 June 2019
Is that a B'Stard I see before me?
A crowded field but where is the quality?
They say that fact is stranger than fiction and nowhere is
this more true than in British politics right now. Thirty years ago, the TV
scriptwriters Laurence Marks and Maurice Gran satirised the Conservative Party
of the 1980s in the TV sitcom The New Statesman.
It was based around the fictional hard-right Tory MP, Alan B’Stard, who was
portrayed as an unscrupulous, amoral individual who would stop at nothing to
fulfil his ambitions. It is difficult to watch this clip and avoid the impression that many of the current candidates for the Tory leadership
are aping B’Stard’s fictional rhetoric.
Nominations for the Conservative Party leadership closed
today, with 10 candidates on the ballot paper and with the first round of voting due to take place on Thursday. Just as a reminder
of what is at stake, 314 Tory MPs are due to choose two candidates to succeed
Theresa May who will then face a ballot of all Party members. What this means
is that 124,000 people will choose the person who will attempt to negotiate the
UK’s departure from the EU. Or, to put it another way, this choice will be made
by 0.27% of the total electorate. Moreover, if only one candidate emerges from
the parliamentary process, as happened in 2016, the new PM will be chose by
less than 0.01% of all eligible voters[1].
To highlight the New Statesman-like surrealism of the debate, three of the
candidates (Rory Stewart,
Andrea Leadsom and Michael Gove)
have all admitted to past drugs misdemeanours. Two of the hardline Brexiteer
candidates (Dominic Raab and Esther McVey)
have suggested suspending parliament to ensure that it cannot block Brexit on
31 October. And this is before we get to Boris Johnson whose strained relationship with the truth is legendary.
Welcome to democracy in 21st century Britain.
Reviewing the fiscal options
But for all the lack of quality on display to inherit the
office held by substantial politicians such as Winston Churchill and Margaret
Thatcher, the economic issue of interest concerns the fiscal policy options suggested
by the candidates. Let’s start with Boris Johnson. He has already threatened to
withhold the £39 billion payment for incurred liabilities unless the EU gives
the UK better exit terms. But assuming this is paid over a period of 3 years,
it only amounts to around 10% of the EU’s annual budget revenues (or 0.1% of EU
GDP). Not only is it a trifling sum in the grand scheme of things but lawyers
suggest that such a move is probably illegal. It would also be the first time
since the UK came into existence following the Act of Union in 1707 that it has
defaulted on its credit obligations. The EU simply will not be threatened in
this way and it would cost the UK far more than it gains. Whilst such a policy
may play well with the Tory faithful, it would be an act of monumental economic
stupidity.
Various leadership candidates have also promised tax cuts in
the event they accede to 10 Downing Street. Johnson has promised to raise the
threshold for the higher rate of income tax (40%) from a starting salary of
£50,000 to £80,000, at an estimated cost of £10 bn (around 0.5% of GDP).
Johnson claims that this can be funded from the £26.6 bn set aside by the
Treasury as an insurance fund against a no-deal Brexit. But since Johnson
has threatened that the UK would be prepared to walk away from the EU without a deal,
he is surely going to need the emergency fund. Johnson’s team counter that the
policy would be part funded by raising the upper limit on national insurance
contributions. However, the Institute for Fiscal Studies has pointed out that
this would benefit richer pensioners who do not pay NICs – which, oddly enough,
maps onto the Conservative Party membership demographic.
Meanwhile, Brexiteer Dominic Raab has suggested reducing the
basic rate of income tax by 5 percentage points over a period of five years. A
rough rule of thumb based on Treasury calculations suggests that this will
reduce revenues by more than 1% of GDP on a five-year horizon with no
suggestion of how this will be funded. Foreign Secretary Jeremy Hunt, who is
also in the running, has called for a huge increase in defence spending to “support our great ally, the United States.”
Currently, the UK spends around 2% of GDP on defence – each one percentage
point increase will raise outlays by £20 bn. Maybe former Health Secretary Hunt
thinks he can find more for defence by taking something away from the health
budget or perhaps in contrast to his rivals, he believes taxes should be
raised. But like his rivals, he has failed to set out how his plans will be
funded.
We should also not forget Michael Gove’s plan to abolish VAT
and replace it with a lower, simpler sales tax. Interesting theory but a bad
policy. For one thing, it is one of the government’s biggest revenue
generators, delivering £138 bn per year to the Exchequer (6.3% of GDP). Moreover
it is a general tax involving the production and distribution of goods and the
provision of services, and whilst it is borne by the final consumer it is more
than simply a sales tax. VAT is also efficient, in contrast to Purchase Tax
which it replaced and which was levied on a range of goods at differing rates.
It was certainly not efficient. If Gove’s proposed tax is “simple” it will have
to be applied to a wide range of goods in order to generate the kind of revenue
that VAT does currently, which raises questions of whether items such as food
will remain exempt.
Then there is the question of how it impacts on the supply
chain. If it is levied at every stage of the process, a “simple” 5% rate on a
chain with five links results in a 27% tax rate compared to the current VAT
rate of 20%. Moreover, if an exporter is the final link in the chain they will
not be able to recoup the tax paid without raising their international selling
price, which would render their product uncompetitive. In short, switching away
from VAT would involve far more complexity than Gove believes. A simpler tax
which is revenue neutral would require a lot of thought and would almost
certainly prove impossible to implement before the next election. There is a
reason why 166 of 213 UN members have adopted VAT and why India has just rolled
it out. It is simple and more efficient than the alternatives.
The fact that the Tory front-runners have made taxation such
a big part of their leadership bids reflects the lack of new ideas coming from
the political right. Reducing direct taxes worked in the 1980s because previous
levels of tax were too high so there were some incentive effects derived from cuts.
In addition, there was a large rise in female labour force participation which
helped swell income tax coffers. However, the UK did not face the problem of an
ageing society which it does today. As a consequence the UK does not have the
same scope to cut taxes without major consequences for future public
liabilities. Having endured nine years of austerity to bring public finances
back into line, it would be fiscally irresponsible to waste all the hard work on
unfunded tax cuts which benefit particular interest groups simply to win the
race for Number 10.
[1] Admittedly,
voters do not vote for the PM directly since they only get to choose their
local representative. But there is no doubt that their local choices are
determined by national level issues.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)