Monday, 13 November 2017

It's very quiet out there

As UK political uncertainty mounts, it is striking that sterling-denominated assets have held up reasonably well of late. Sterling has traded in a relatively narrow range over the past year with the trade weighted index registering a high of 79 in May and a low of 74 in August. Surprisingly, investor net speculative positions in sterling, which were heavily negative early this year, have now turned flat to slightly positive. This reflects the fact that FX investors are currently not expecting a significant sterling collapse, although the timing of the move does appear to be correlated with changes in the market’s position on BoE rate hikes. Meanwhile, although the FTSE100 has trailed indices such as the Eurostoxx  50 year-to-date, they have moved broadly in line since May and the FTSE has managed a year-to-date return of 3.8%  – not great when set against other markets but nonetheless positive. Moreover, the weakness of sterling tends to be a positive factor for UK equities given how much revenue is booked in foreign currencies (around 70%).

Thus, political uncertainty appears to be conspicuous by its absence so far as markets are concerned, which reflects the fact that investors are looking through all the rhetoric and concluding that the likelihood of a cliff-edge Brexit is low. Since we are still more than 16 months away from the expiry of the Article 50 negotiation phase, markets take the view that there is no sense in panicking now – there will be plenty of time for that later. Nonetheless, the closer we get to the deadline without agreement, the greater the likelihood that assets will come under pressure, but that is probably a story for next year.

To get a sense of how the market and economic agents assess uncertainty in the UK at present, I constructed an uncertainty index based upon eight variables: (i) FTSE100 equity volatility; (ii) EUR/GBP FX volatility; (iii) GBP/USD FX volatility; (iv) the Baker, Bloom and Davis policy uncertainty indicator; (v) GfK survey data for expected consumer finances; (vi)  expected unemployment and (vii) expected economic situation. The final component is (viii) the CBI’s estimate of uncertainty as a factor limiting capex. Furthermore, if we strip out the equity and currency vol measures, we have a five variable index of domestic uncertainty.

The chart suggests that the aggregate uncertainty index has dipped back close to its long-term average (2000-2015). Whilst the domestic indicator has not fallen quite as sharply, it is well below its summer 2016 highs with only the Baker et al policy uncertainty index showing any extended deviation. The interesting thing is that this policy uncertainty index is based on an online trawl of newspaper websites looking for various keywords which express uncertainty. To the extent that much of the concern expressed about Brexit has indeed come via the media (not to mention the blogosphere, so I am as guilty as anyone), it highlights the noise inherent in the debate without necessarily shedding much light on how the economy is performing. Indeed, many of the other indicators normalised very quickly, which suggests that most economic agents generally got on with life in the wake of the Brexit vote.

This does not mean to say that everything will remain so quiet. The GfK survey data point to a deterioration in expectations for the future economic situation with sentiment now back at levels last seen in spring 2013. Moreover, with inflation beginning to put the squeeze on consumers, we are starting to see some deterioration in expectations for consumer finances.

It is worth noting that the indicator is not a good predictor of longer-term trends. Even in the early months of 2008, when there were signs that trouble was brewing in the banking sector and the economy was losing some momentum, both the aggregate and domestic uncertainty indices remained at low levels. A lurch towards the cliff-edge of Brexit could change perceptions quite markedly. Perhaps UK consumers and corporates need to hurt even more before they realise the potential economic consequences of Brexit. This is why just looking at the current relative stability of the uncertainty index is not necessarily a good guide to future trends. In my view – and that of most of the economics profession – a number of senior British politicians do not seem to understand the risk they are taking with the wider economy. It is incumbent upon them to get it right or the electorate may be in a less forgiving mood than it has been of late.

Saturday, 11 November 2017

We'll settle for either strong or stable

Anyone looking at the UK from the outside can be forgiven for wondering what has gone wrong with a political process that the British like to think spawned the Mother of all Parliaments (there again, many natives are wondering the same thing). The government is weak and divided – in office but not in power – whilst the political establishment has been rocked by allegations of sexual misconduct. All this is happening against a backdrop of the most critical set of negotiations since 1945, which require the government’s undivided attention – but which it is unable to give for the reasons just outlined.

The obvious answer is that Brexit is the culprit. According to Philip Stephens, writing in the FT, “Brexit has broken British politics." There is certainly a lot of truth in this. As Stephens notes, “a majority of MPs think Brexit is a mistake but feel obliged to pursue it lest they be accused of defying what the tabloids declare to be ‘the will of the people.’” Quite what the “will of the people” might be is hard to discern from a referendum result which produced a near 50-50 outcome. Consequently, and unsurprisingly, treating the result of a (legally non-binding) referendum in the same way as a winner-takes-all election was always going to polarise already-inflamed opinions.

But a less obvious answer is that the Brexit vote was itself the manifestation of something deeper. Arguably – and I am in speculative territory here – it was the result of dissatisfaction with a political establishment which has failed to adhere to the rules and standards which it expects others to abide by. More worryingly for an economist, there has been a steady erosion of rules- and evidence-based policy making which has contributed to hugely sub-optimal outcomes. We can go back to 2002 and the case which the UK government made for involvement in a military invasion of Iraq which was not sanctioned by the United Nations. The UK Prime Minister Tony Blair put his name to a document that argued the government of Saddam Hussain had developed weapons of mass destruction, despite the fact that international observers on the ground found no such evidence. Trust in UK politicians was further eroded by the 2009 parliamentary expenses scandal in which many MPs blatantly ignored guidelines on the use of public money in reclaiming expenses. There were rules in place but they were routinely flouted.

A more economically relevant case is the flouting of the fiscal rules enshrined in the Maastricht Treaty, designed to prevent governments from running a deficit-to-GDP ratio in excess of 3%. Moreover, the criteria for entry into the single currency in the first place was that “the gross debt total of the general government should not exceed the reference value of 60 percent of GDP or, if it does, it should be sufficiently diminishing and approaching the reference value at a satisfactory pace.” With both Belgium and Italy showing debt ratios above 100% at end-1997 (the reference date for entry into EMU), it’s safe to say that they were nowhere near achieving this goal. Of the original 11 members Austria, France, Ireland, Netherlands and Spain also missed the target.

I did point out in 2003, at a time when investors were concerned that countries were routinely missing the 3% deficit target that “by failing to force governments to comply more strictly with the 60% deficit:GDP ratio prior to the start of Emu, the fiscal playing field has not been levelled sufficiently to allow some countries to easily meet the Stability and Growth Pact deficit criteria. In simple terms, the debt targets were simply not taken seriously enough.” This is not to say that the euro zone debt crisis could have been avoided, but had debt ratios been closer to the required thresholds in the first place, some of the smaller countries would have had more fiscal headroom to cope with the storms which subsequently blew in.

The banking crisis, which resulted in many financial institutions requiring government support, is another case in point. The public’s view is that the taxpayer has carried a heavy burden without those responsible for causing the problem ever being held properly to account. Again, this could be seen as a failure to apply rules – or at least the failure to apply natural justice.

Each of the examples outlined here was avoidable. Had one occurred in isolation, arguably we could have coped better with the fallout. But failure to consistently apply the rules erodes policy legitimacy and invokes greater challenges to the status quo, producing an ideal breeding ground for political discontent. The academic literature in this area explains how policies which are initially not popular (such as Brexit) can find broader acceptance as the public taps into various aspects of the policy (see the introduction to this paper from The Quality of Governance Institute at the University of Gothenburg).

The authors of this paper also make the point that “public opinion changes as a result of policy implementation.” Given the UK government’s abject failure to get its act together on many aspects of policy, this raises serious legitimacy issues. Not only did successive UK governments fail to deal consistently with the conditions which provoked the Brexit backlash, but the current administration is failing to deal with the consequences. Theresa May once promised to deliver strong and stable government. Right now, many people would settle for one or the other.

Wednesday, 8 November 2017

Breaking point

In the context of the debate on productivity, I was recently asked by a non-economist why economists tend to assume mean reversion when it is clear there has been a structural break in the series. It is a very good question and goes to the heart of a major problem in the business of forecasting. Most of our forecasting models are based on linear (or log-linearised) relationships whose forecast performance is conditioned by historical experience. Therefore, if a relationship has tended to mean-revert in the past, the model will assume it does so in future. As a consequence, we cannot easily deal with structural breaks in economic relationships. To put it another way, even if the data deviates from past performance for a prolonged period of time, it is dangerous to assume that there has been a permanent shift since it is entirely possible that it will soon snap back.

It takes a lot to convince economists that there has been a change in trends. In a classic 1961 paper[1], Lawrence Klein and Richard Kosobud noted that much of macroeconomics is based on five “great ratios” in which the relationships between variables can be assumed to be stable. These five ratios are (i) the savings-income ratio; (ii) the capital-output ratio; (iii) labour's share of income; (iv) income velocity of circulation and (v) the capital-labour ratio. But what might have been true almost six decades ago is no longer the case. Labour’s share in income has fallen sharply in the Anglo-Saxon economies over recent years whilst recent experience has shown big shifts in the capital-output ratio, which resulted in the productivity puzzle. However, these old ideas die hard and whilst we try to ensure that we do not stick to outdated precepts, relationships often change so imperceptibly slowly that it is difficult to be sure whether we are witnessing a cyclical shift or a secular trend.

The problem is well-known in economics and has been much-studied. In my introductory econometrics classes one of the first statistical tests to which I was introduced was the Chow test for structural breaks which assesses whether the coefficients derived from regressions on two different parts of the dataset are equal. Although it is pretty simple stuff, a look at UK year-on-year employment and GDP growth over the period 1980 to 2016 nicely highlights the nature of the problem. A quick glance at the chart certainly suggests that there has been a change in the trend relationship (chart). But it is really not that simple.

Suppose in 2013 a policymaker began to be concerned about the nature of the relationship and suspected there was a break in the historical trend. In early 2013, the intelligent policymaker has quarterly data through to end-2012 and decides to estimate a simple econometric equation using the EViews software over the period 1980 to 2012 (132 observations) in order to test their hypothesis. But conducting a Chow test for a structural break at the end of 2008, 2009 and 2010 does not yield any evidence of a break. The data-driven policymaker would thus conclude that this is problem to keep under observation but it is not yet time to press the panic button. A year later, in early 2014, the policymaker runs the analysis again with an additional four quarters of data (136 observations) but still finds no evidence of a structural break in the relationship. But by early 2015, our policymaker runs the analysis on data through end-2014 and finds some evidence of a break in the data at the end of 2009. By the time we get to early 2016 – three years after they suspect a problem – the statistical evidence is unambiguous: There has been a change in the relationship between GDP growth and employment.

The first point to make clear here is that a cautious policymaker has to wait for evidence that there has been a productivity shift – even if they suspected that something was amiss, they cannot make inferences on a relatively small amount of data because they do not know whether the shift is temporary or permanent. But even when the statistical evidence is clear, we cannot simply jump to conclusions – the blip in the productivity figures could vanish just as suddenly as it appeared. For example, if labour shortages begin to manifest themselves, companies can only increase output by increasing capital investment rather than relying on labour. This will mean GDP grows more rapidly than employment in which case labour productivity figures would begin to look much stronger.

As noted above, this is a simplistic exercise and there are better statistical ways to assess whether there are breaks in a data series, but it does highlight an important point: In a world where we require empirical evidence before making policy changes, we sometimes have to wait a long time to build up sufficient information before we are even half sure that we are doing the right thing. Whilst the BoE and OBR are criticised for failing to foresee these trend shifts in economic performance, anyone who has ever tried modelling and forecasting when trends are changing will tell you that it is much harder than it looks.



[1] Klein, L.R. and R. F. Kosobud (1961) ‘Some Econometrics of Growth: Great Ratios of Economics,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics (75), 173-198

Sunday, 5 November 2017

The great productivity debate remains unresolved

Over the course of the last week I have listened to presentations from three of the UK’s most influential forecasting institutions (the Institute for Fiscal Studies, National Institute of Economic and Social Research and BoE) in which the common factor was the weakness – indeed lack – of productivity growth. The ONS measures productivity using three main metrics – output per worker, per job and per hour. In the nine years since the great recession, these have grown by 0.8%, 1.0% and -0.2% respectively. For the avoidance of any doubt, these reflect the absolute changes across a nine year span, not the annual average – in other words, output per hour has declined in absolute terms by 0.2% since Q4 2007 (do you feel as though you are working less?).

To put this into context, annual growth over the period 1980 to 2008 averaged 2% for output per worker; 1.3% per job and 1.4% per hour which means that output per worker is currently almost 13% below its pre-crisis trend (chart). You really have to go back a long way to see a sustained period of sluggish productivity as poor as this in the UK during peacetime – probably back to pre-industrial revolution times, if the BoE’s excellent long-run historical dataset is any guide.


On the assumption that real wages grow in line with productivity, this means that real wages today are a similar amount below where they would otherwise be. But what makes matters worse is that, miserable though productivity growth has been, UK real wages have lagged even further behind. Average weekly earnings deflated by the CPI are currently 4.6% below their end-2007 levels. In other words, productivity growth has been flat but real wages have fallen. This goes to highlight the claim made by Paul Krugman that productivity may not be everything, but in the long run it is almost everything. It is undoubtedly one of the reasons why we all feel so much worse off than we did prior to the recession.

None of this is exactly news, as it has been a mounting cause for concern in recent years. Indeed, I recall looking at the problem as long ago as 2013. But the fact that productivity has remained stubbornly weak, and not recovered in line with expectations (and indeed, historical experience) clearly points to something wrong. It might be partly the result of measurement error in an increasingly digital economy; labour hoarding in a service driven economy; a lack of investment or simply an ageing demographic profile. It is, of course, not just a UK problem: It is a problem across all industrialised economies although the UK seems to have been hit relatively hard. Nonetheless it is an issue which governments have tended to downplay up to now.

Each of the three UK institutions noted above sees different aspects of the problem, reflecting their particular speciality. For the NIESR, it will contribute to weak growth and thus an ongoing squeeze on living standards. As far as the IFS is concerned, whose focus is fiscal policy, the resultant weakness of growth will put pressure on the economy’s ability to generate sufficient revenue to eliminate the budget deficit. Indeed, the Office for Budget Responsibility last month noted that it is likely to “significantly” reduce its “assumption for potential productivity growth over the next five years“ in its November forecast which accompanies the Autumn budget statement. Meanwhile, the BoE is concerned that weak productivity growth will hold back potential output growth with the result that the economy is more likely to run into capacity constraints which will generate inflation.

So far, we seem to have escaped the worst aspects of sluggish productivity growth. Inflation has only picked up because of a sterling-induced crash, not because of any underlying rise in domestic cost pressure. Public finances have improved significantly, with public borrowing declining by two-thirds between 2010 and 2017. Arguably the squeeze on living standards has been the worst aspect, and may well have contributed to the Brexit vote last year. But the sunny uplands to which politicians promise we will soon return will remain unattainable without a recovery in productivity. And the longer productivity remains weak, the more of a struggle economic recovery will be. Like a Facebook relationship status, the productivity puzzle is complicated but it is one we need to get a handle on – and fast.

Tuesday, 31 October 2017

The BoE and a bit of cold turkey

It is widely expected that the Bank of England will raise interest rates this week for the first time since 2007. There have been some influential academic voices suggesting that this would be the wrong time to raise rates – the more I think about it, the more I disagree with them. And before we all get carried away, the expected increase from 0.25% to 0.5% would only represent a move from the lowest level in history to the second lowest.

The first reason for disagreeing with some of the wiser heads is purely to do with the signalling effect. Having suggested in September that “some withdrawal of monetary stimulus was likely to be appropriate over the coming months” financial markets have increasingly interpreted this as meaning that a rate move is likely in November and are now pricing such action with a probability of almost 90%. Although the BoE has suggested in the past that a near-term rate hike might be in the offing – which subsequently never materialised – not since Mark Carney assumed his post in 2013 have markets been so convinced about the likelihood of a rate hike at the upcoming meeting as they are now. The only comparable degree of market conviction was in the wake of the EU referendum, when in July 2016 markets fully priced a 25 bps rate cut at the August 2016 MPC meeting (a reduction which was duly delivered).

Of course, it is not the MPC’s job to reinforce the market’s conviction. But to the extent that the strategy of forward guidance relies on the predictability and credibility of central bank communication, any decision to hold interest rates unchanged in view of current market expectations would seriously undermine this plank of monetary policy because it would suggest that communication has not been sufficiently clear.

Another strong argument in favour of raising interest rates is that they are (arguably) too low given where we are in the economic cycle. Much of the academic opposition to a rate hike stems from the fact that wage inflation remains low, and uncertainty surrounding the Brexit decision suggests that this is not a good time to tighten policy. I have sympathy with these views. Indeed, I have argued recently that the inflation excuse used to justify the need for higher interest rates does not wash because it reflects a one-off spike triggered by currency depreciation. But opponents of a rate hike may be guilty of confusing the impact of interest rate levels and a change in rates. Even though the UK economy has lost momentum over the course of this year it is still growing at a rate of around 1.5% in real terms. Inflation, at 3%, is right at the top end of the threshold above which the BoE Governor has to write to the Chancellor explaining what he intends to do in order to bring it back towards target. Moreover, monetary policy is still operating on a setting designed to promote recovery in the wake of the 2008 financial collapse, with an additional bit of Brexit insurance thrown in. The UK simply does not need rates at current levels.

Arguably, the BoE should have raised rates in 2014 or 2015 when growth was back at trend and house price inflation was running at double-digit rates. However, the global interest rate cycle was not then supportive of a unilateral move by the BoE, with the Fed not yet having commenced its rate hiking cycle and the ECB beginning a phase of more aggressive monetary easing. As it turned out, with UK inflation running close to zero during 2015 and H1 2016, the BoE would have run the risk of repeating the mistake of the Swedish Riksbank which began tightening in 2010 only to have to reverse course in the face of a collapse in inflation.

As for Brexit risks, the BoE has been clear all along that this represents an economic shock against which interest rates can only provide limited insulation. In any case, taking back the precautionary 25 bps rate cut implemented in summer 2016 makes sense in view of the fact that the worst case scenario did not materialise. But a wider point is that ultra-expansionary monetary policy can inflict just as much harm as an overly restrictive stance – perhaps in ways we do not yet fully understand. We do know that low interest rates have helped to propel equity markets to record highs and produced an unjustified tightening of credit spreads. To the extent that investors have become less discriminating about what they buy when they are simply chasing yield, low interest rates distort normal market behaviour. And as the Japanese experience has shown, a lax monetary stance is no guarantee of economic recovery.

Rising interest rates will hurt – mortgage payments, for example, will go up which is no fun at a time when real wages are falling. But as those professionals treating drug addicts will tell you, sometimes it is necessary to take a clear look at where we are, how we have got there and accept that a bit of cold turkey is necessary for the longer term good.

Saturday, 28 October 2017

The Bitcoin bubble in context

Over the course of recent months I have done a lot of work looking at Bitcoin and have watched its recent sharp ascent with a mixture of bemusement and concern. I do not intend here to go into a detailed description of how the currency operates and refer the interested reader to the website Bitcoin.org  for an overview. Instead I want to focus on the sharp surge in the price of Bitcoin which has seen its value against the dollar increase by a factor of almost six since the start of 2017.

The puzzling question is why its value should have risen so sharply this year – after all, it has been around for seven years and we have already been through one boom and bust episode. In 2013 Bitcoin’s value against the dollar surged by a factor of 83, only for it to fall back by 85% over the next 14 months. What is rather more of a concern today is that the market value of all Bitcoin in circulation stands at $99 billion versus $9 billion in late-2013, and one of the questions which has been posed to me in recent days is whether an implosion of the Bitcoin bubble represents a threat to financial stability in a way which it did not in 2013.

As to the first of these questions, I believe that the rally in Bitcoin this year represents a different sort of bubble to that of four years ago. In 2013 there was genuine interest in Bitcoin as an alternative currency. Much of this optimism was misplaced, however, as the disadvantages of digital cryptocurrencies became evident. For example, the huge variability in the price of Bitcoin means that it does not represent a stable store of value. Together with security issues – the collapse of the Mt. Gox Bitcoin exchange in 2014 being a case in point – investors began to rethink their Bitcoin strategy.

But the currency is underpinned by the blockchain – a distributed ledger which potentially has a huge range of applications outside the realms of the currency world. One of the fastest growing digital currencies this year is Ether which is created as a by-product of the Ethereum network – a blockchain technology with wider applications than that used for Bitcoin. But as investors have jumped on the blockchain bandwagon so they have forced up the value of the digital currencies which these systems churn out.

In many ways, the digital currency revolution is reminiscent of the dot-com bubble of the late 1990s: There are many new and interesting applications of the blockchain technology but they have yet to be fully realised. Accordingly, investors are paying for their potential rather than their realised value, and because it is almost impossible to put a price on potential value, they are overpaying. It is thus hard to avoid the conclusion that current Bitcoin valuations represent a bubble which is set to burst at some point. As a historical guide, I have compared data for the 14 months prior to the Bitcoin peak versus the late-1990s Nasdaq rally and the Tulipmania bubble of 1636-37. As is clear from the chart, the surge in Bitcoin outstrips the surge in equity valuations in 1999-2000 but would appear not to match up to events in the Netherlands almost 400 years ago. But given the poor quality of the data for tulip prices in the 1630s and the fact that we may not be comparing like with like (different types of tulip bulb sold for different prices), we should be careful in making comparisons. But the fact that the Bitcoin boom far outstrips the Nasdaq rally of the late-1990s demonstrates that this is a boom to be taken seriously.

On its own, the bursting of the Bitcoin bubble should not in theory impact most investors. Indeed, the market cap of all digital currencies represents only around 0.3% of global GDP. Moreover, China is increasingly the dominant player in the Bitcoin market, accounting for the vast majority of coins created. It is thus likely that much of the Bitcoin wealth is held by domestic Chinese investors who will bear the brunt of any price collapse (for a fascinating overview of the impact of the digital currency in the Middle Kingdom, this article from Quartz is worth a read).

However, there are residual concerns that a collapse in Bitcoin could be a canary in the coalmine for a more widespread asset price correction, following years of easy money which has pumped up equities and real estate prices. My guess is that this is unlikely and that the spillover effects will be limited, precisely because of the narrow base upon which Bitcoin ownership rests. But as IMF Managing Director Christine Lagard once said, “I'm of those who believe that excesses in all matters are not a good idea … whether it's excess in the financial market, whether it's excess of inequality, it has to be watched, it has to be measured, and it has to be anticipated in terms of consequences.” We should thus not be complacent if the Bitcoin bubble bursts. It might have a deeper meaning than we can currently ascertain.

Tuesday, 24 October 2017

Get a grip

In recent days I have come across a couple of insightful articles which expose the lack of new thinking at the heart of the Conservative Party which goes a long way towards explaining why the Brexit vote happened and why the negotiations are not going as hoped. In an article at the weekend, Will Hutton argued very forcibly that the party’s inability to consign the Thatcher years to history is preventing it from moving forward (here). We have to allow for the fact that Hutton has a particular political bent, with his Wikipedia page describing him as being “widely known for his advocacy of centre-left policies.” That said, his article did hit many issues on the nail.

Hutton was particularly critical of former chancellor Nigel Lawson who “in any league table of national figures who have been consistently wrong on almost every major judgment … must rank close to number one … Yet, extraordinarily, he is the ringleader of a group of Thatcherite ultras who now crowd on to our airwaves, exploiting the mythology of Thatcherite greatness to insist Britain must make a complete break with the EU.” In 2016, Lawson wrote an article for the FT in which he claimed “Brexit gives us a chance to finish the Thatcher revolution.” But Hutton points out that many of the supply-side reforms of which Lawson is so proud are now beginning to unravel. The tide of opinion has turned against privatisation as society increasingly questions who has reaped the benefits. The financial deregulation over which Lawson presided was one of the contributory factors to the UK banking collapse in 2008, and also helped to widen regional imbalances as London benefited whilst other parts of the country lagged behind. Finally, the labour market reforms of the 1980s, which emasculated the trade unions, are increasingly being seen as one of the reasons why workers are being squeezed despite unemployment at 40-year lows.

It also raises a question of why a politician who left front-line politics almost 30 years ago should still be invited to opine on economic matters. Is the party really so devoid of new thinking? Indeed, I still find it odd that a man who was aged 84 at the time of the EU referendum should have had such a prominent role in the Leave campaign, when he is unlikely to be around to see the long-term effects. Moreover, I do not recall that in the 1980s any of Nigel Lawson’s predecessors from 30 years previously enjoyed such a prominent media profile as he does today (still less calling for the sacking of the incumbent, as Lawson recently demanded of Philip Hammond). Lawson was a bold, self-confident reformer in his day but his time has passed. Unfortunately, many members of his party appear not to have realised that time has moved on and that the solutions of the 1980s may not be appropriate today.

This is indeed a point I have made on this blog in recent months (here, for example). But the blogger Pete North offered an impassioned critique of the problems facing the Conservatives (here – it’s a fine post which deserves a read). More to the point, it explains very eloquently how the current iteration of Conservative economic policy differs from what went before, and gets to the heart of an issue that I have spent much time trying to explain to foreign friends and family. North notes that whilst aspiration was at the centre of Conservative policy during the Thatcher era “there was also something about Mrs Thatcher's values that made her version of conservatism the definitive one. There was something more than just the slash and burn free market instinct. There was still an underlying obligation to observe that, as citizens, we are custodians of a particularly British order where enterprise sits comfortably alongside the institutions of state.” He goes on to state (admittedly in a less than temperate fashion) that “I don't see that in the modern Conservative Party. For the most part I see the dregs of Thatcherism and the second generation Toryboys wedded to extreme free market dogma - which is no respecter of anything … It is this corrosive trend that is ultimately shredding the social contract.

You can argue about the nature of the language he uses, but his point about the shredding of the social contract is a valid one. The recent experience of having to wait almost four weeks for an appointment with my local GP is an indication that there is something badly wrong with local health provision. Indeed, North argues, as I have done, that if this were consistent with the operation of a free market policy “we should at least be seeing some sort of corresponding tax cuts” as compensation for the reduction in service.

But the wider point is this: A large swathe of the Conservative party has been captured by the ultras who see Brexit as an end in itself. This in turn has divided the party which is scared that the diametrically opposing economic solutions offered by the Labour Party are increasingly finding electoral favour. As a result, the whole government appears to have turned in on itself in a bout of vicious in-fighting and has less time (or perhaps just the stomach) to tackle the mounting economic problems caused by failed welfare reforms such as the botched rollout of Universal Credit (here and here).

We may not yet be quite at the McCarthyism stage here in the UK but as Robert Peston tweeted today, the current state of public discourse “is redolent of a country suffering a Brexit-induced nervous breakdown.” Given the magnitude of the economic challenges ahead (Brexit, flatlining productivity, overly-indebted households, the lack of adequate pension savings for many people), the UK really needs a government that can get a grip – and fast.