I wrote a piece yesterday which indicated how the UK
government’s position on Brexit is no longer tenable and needs to change. The
extent to which this impacted on the election is questionable. But one issue
which did appear to resonate during the campaign was that of fiscal austerity.
Like Brexit, this is a subject where I believe the government has adopted an
ideological rather than a pragmatic approach, and the evidence from the
election campaign is that it is wearing a bit thin.
During the election campaign of 2010, the Conservatives
portrayed the Labour Party as having bankrupted the country as the public
deficit headed above 10% of GDP. Labour were admittedly fiscally profligate in
the years prior to the crisis but the crash in public finances was purely the
result of the massive collapse in activity in the wake of the recession. Nonetheless,
the Conservatives played on the image relentlessly, usurping Labour from
government in 2010 and embarking on a fiscally prudent course to eliminate the
current deficit by 2016 and reduce overall borrowing to 1% of GDP. As is well known, for various reasons
Chancellor George Osborne continued to fall short of his targets and the fiscal
squeeze became ever tighter.
What was deemed to be particularly unfair about Osborne’s
approach is that he relentlessly targeted the welfare budget. Access to welfare
has been severely restricted as those people previously judged unfit for work are subject to more stringent tests, which are almost impossible to pass unless
the individual is virtually dead. Leave to appeal has been strictly curtailed, with
a recent Freedom of Information request revealing that the Department for Work and Pensions has a target to reject 80%
of benefits appeals. As even The Economist noted recently, welfare spending has fallen “by one percentage point of GDP, with working-age families bearing the
brunt. Since 2015, however, the Tories have turned a hard-nosed welfare policy
into a punitive one. Osborne used cuts in working-age benefits as a way to
balance the books … A four-year cash-terms freeze on most benefits began in
April last year. That policy was announced when inflation was close to zero. Now
it is nearing 3%, the purchasing power of everything from tax credits (top-ups
for low-paid folk) to housing benefit is falling.”
The recent tragic terror attacks on the British mainland
threw the issue of public spending cuts into sharp relief. I have noted previously that politicians are quick to praise public services when they are needed but
otherwise have no compunction in cutting their budgets. Having survived in
government by the skin of their teeth, the Conservatives now realise that a
further parliamentary term of fiscal austerity is not going to win them votes.
But what exactly might that entail? Does it mean simply not reducing the share
of spending relative to GDP any further? Or does it mean holding the deficit
constant versus GDP, which allows scope to raise spending so long as it is
funded by higher taxes? As it is, spending as a share of GDP is still high by
past standards, at just over 39%, but it is 6 percentage points below the 2010
peak. But revenues, at just below 37% of GDP, are only slightly higher than
their long-run average. My sense is that taxes will have to rise at some point
in order to fund additional spending – and as I have long argued, the policy of
cutting corporate taxes to amongst the lowest in the OECD is putting an
unnecessary hole in public revenues.
But austerity is not just about making the books balance: It
becomes a state of mind, whether you are in government, the private sector or
making your household finances stretch further. It is in this wider context
that we have to view the horrific fire which engulfed the Grenfell Tower in
London yesterday. I am not suggesting for a moment that government neglect had
any bearing on what happened. But abstracting from the grim horror of what
happened, one of my thoughts was that 30 years ago, as the UK was going through
a similar period of government retrenchment, we experienced a similar series of
tragedies (the Bradford City fire;
the Kings Cross fire;
the sinking of the Marchioness and the Clapham rail disaster).
David Aaronovitch, writing in The Times today, evidently came to the same
conclusion. As he put it, these disasters “arose
from the use of old, near-obsolete and dangerous infrastructure … Stuff like
this usually comes down to attitude and to money.” Elsewhere in the same
newspaper, the point was made that “cost-cutting
by private firms brings public danger.”
This is not the voice of the Labour Party: The Times
represents the voice of the political centre with a bias towards the
Conservatives. This shift in attitudes must act as a wake-up call to
politicians of all stripes that government – whether central or local – cannot
continue outsourcing functions to the private sector. Citizens pay their
not-insubstantial taxes and expect a decent level of services in return. When
even the BBC news reporter covering the fire (here at 5:24 if you can play the video) – who as a rule remains impartial at all
times – stated “in the 21st century,
in a country with some of the strictest fire regulations in the world, a
desperate tragedy like this just should not happen,” you know that
something is afoot.
The disastrous performance of the Conservative Party in last
week's election has prompted a rethink of policy on both Brexit and fiscal austerity.
This is recognition of the fact that the government has been spectacularly
wrong on both – as I have long pointed out – and the scale of the U-turn reflects
a certain degree of chutzpah. In this post I will focus on Brexit-related
issues and leave the fiscal issues for my next post.
Whilst hopes have been awakened that we will see a softening
of the terms on which the UK seeks to leave the EU, it is just as likely that
we will end up instead with a chaotic Brexit which would be the worst of all
worlds. I have always maintained that the Brexit referendum was an unjustified
gamble with the national interest and it feels even more like that today. Those politicians who advocated this course
of action deserve all the opprobrium that is heaped upon them, and in order to
highlight why Theresa May’s government is not fit to negotiate the exit, it is
worthwhile recalling the series of miscalculations which has characterised Conservative
policy in recent years.
First, the decision to hold the referendum at all was
reckless. This was compounded by the failure to specify the terms which would
make it easy for David Cameron to achieve his objective of winning. For
example, the 1979 Scottish devolution referendum required that a winning margin
be obtained from 40% of all eligible voters. In an uncanny echo of the Brexit
result, whilst 51.6% of those who turned out voted in favour of devolution,
only 32.9% of all eligible voters did so (the corresponding figure in last
year’s referendum was 37%). Then there was the failure to set out ahead of the
event the terms on which the UK would leave. Had voters known exactly what a
hard Brexit entails, some may have thought twice. To cap it all, Theresa May gambled
that the electorate would back her view of a hard Brexit. This proved to be a
second successive failed gamble by a Conservative prime minister which has made
the process of trying to find a Brexit deal far more complicated. Given this
litany of errors, you will forgive my scepticism that the government is best
placed to resolve the difficulties we now face.
Theresa May, described by George Osborne at the weekend as a
dead woman walking, has to find a balance between those MPs in her party who
wish to push for hard Brexit and the large number of MPs who wish to see it
take place on much softer terms, if at all. I was thus somewhat gratified to see
that my idea of a cross-party approach to Brexit now appears to have become a
mainstream idea (you heard it here first).
But we simply should not even be having this debate. A hard
Brexit is a ruinously stupid economic idea. And to compound the negotiating
difficulties by calling an election AFTER the Article 50 process was triggered,
thereby eating up valuable preparation time, tells us all we need to know about
the Conservatives preoccupation with domestic politics rather than the wider
interest. Although the government says it is ready to go ahead with the start
of Brexit talks with the EC next week, it's not clear to me that this can credibly
happen. Technically we do not yet have a government. Nor is it clear what the
UK's negotiating position is, yet they will be facing a European Commission
team which has had months to prepare its case. And just to make life even more difficult, two of the four ministers on the UK’s negotiating team have departed just
days before talks are due to begin. This raises the chances that the disorganised
shambles which passes for government may well crash out of the EU without any
deal. The Conservative manifesto might have said no deal is better than a bad
deal, but that is a level of economic illiteracy which suggests whoever wrote
it has no idea how to conduct international trade negotiations.
Now you may have spotted from the tone of the post that I am
a tad annoyed. Damn right! Pretty much every key decision that has been taken
on Brexit has been wrong. There is no sense that those responsible for making decisions
are capable of thinking strategically about how to get a deal which maximises British
interests. We should be in no doubt that failure to do so will make everyone poorer and despite the talk
which suggests that immigration is the biggest single issue, in the long run
what people care about is their wallet. We are now hearing indications that business
is becoming much more vocal about their needs post-Brexit. So it should. And If
the government does not know what it wants from Brexit, it should not be
entering talks with the EU. Instead it should rescind the Article 50 notice
until such times as it does.
This may annoy the Brexit nutters such as Nigel Farage, who has
threatened a comeback in the event that the government backslides. I say let
him. Farage was a useful dupe for those who wanted something to protest against
in 2016 but he would require the powers of Lazarus to restore UKIP to the
position they were in last year. I also sense that some of last year’s anger has
dissipated somewhat and he would find it difficult to whip up an anti-EU frenzy
in the same way. I do not want Brexit to happen and nothing would please me
more than if the government were to back down. But in the spirit of accepting
the will of the people (even if the referendum is not legally binding) I accept
this is unlikely to happen. But if it has to, then let us work out what
we want first rather than trying to make it up as we go along. That is the path to disaster.
Whilst the headline writers have spent the last two days
poring over the entrails of the UK general election and what it means for the
future direction of economic policy, I have been wondering how the pollsters
could get it so wrong – again. After all, this is the third successive UK
plebiscite since 2015 in which the electoral pundits have failed to call the
result – not to mention their failure to call the US presidential result. If the polls this week had been even slightly
more accurate, the result would not have come as such a surprise and we would
not have spent the last three days having many of the debates about Theresa
May’s future.
First, however, some sense of perspective is in order. The
opinion polls did a pretty good job in getting the voting shares right. The
analysts at Electoral Calculus,
for example, predicted that the Conservative vote share would rise from 37.8%
in 2015 to 43.5% this time around whilst the Labour share would increase from
31.2% to 40%. In the event, the final vote shares were 42.4% and 40%
respectively, so there was a modest overshoot on the Conservative share but
they got Labour spot on. But it is a lot harder to go from there to actually predicting
the election result, because the regional vote distribution matters hugely. In
the UK’s first-past-the-post system, parties only need to outperform their
local rivals by the tiniest of margins to win a seat (indeed, one constituency
was decided by a margin of just 2 votes – 0.00478% of the votes cast). Once we
start digging below the national level, the issue becomes fraught with sample
size problems and the margins of error become much wider.
The opinion polls clearly narrowed over the course of the
campaign. But even by the time the final polls were published on Wednesday
night, the 15-poll average was still showing a Conservative lead of 6 points –
down from 20 in the first half of May – with their polling share only back
where it was when the election was called (43%). The central case forecast was
thus not suggestive of a hung parliament. But if we apply a 5% margin of error,
by adjusting down the Conservative figure and raising Labour’s polling share by
this amount, although the trend does not change the extent of the lead does. Rather
than a 6% margin the Conservatives went into the election with a 2% lead on
this basis (see chart).
Applying this level of statistical inaccuracy in trying to
predict the number of seats becomes a whole order of magnitude more difficult. In
addition to Electoral Calculus (EC), I have also been tracking the results derived
by the Election Forecast group (EF). EC predicted that the
Conservatives would win 358 seats whilst EF’s projection was 366 (though EF’s
low case scenario did predict that the Conservatives would win 318 seats – the right answer as it happens – whilst EC’s
low estimate was 314). The central case predictions were thus off by more than
10%. They were even further off in their predictions for Labour with EC predicting
218 seats and EF (where the outturn was even higher than their upper limit) projecting
207. One group which did predict a hung parliament was YouGov whose “big data”
model proved to be right, but their final call based on conventional survey
methods was for a wider Conservative majority.
One of the reasons for the apparent failure of conventional
methods was that most polling organisations discounted the evidence suggesting
that younger age groups would vote Labour, and assumed that many of them would stay
at home, as happened in 2015. This is an object lesson in the perils of manual
adjustment – something which I do all the time when using structural
macroeconometric models and more often than not, this turns out to be
justified. It is always galling when the model beats your prior view, but ironically,
the next time you let the model run without overwriting the results you often
find you would have been justified in overriding it.
YouGov provided a non-technical summary of their Multilevel
Regression and Post-stratification (MRP) model which seemed to work so well (here).
It takes polling data from the preceding seven days to estimate a model
relating interview date, constituency, voter demographics, past voting
behaviour and other profile variables to their current voting intentions. This is
used to estimate the probability that a voter with specified characteristics
will vote for a particular party. Obviously, it is not infallible: It is a
snapshot of intentions at the time the survey is made. In addition, the models
are based on very small sample sizes so they suffer from the usual bias
problems. Like all models, they are subject to significant margins of error,
and as this blog post highlights they need to be treated cautiously. Indeed, I assign a huge degree of mistrust
to regression models for predictive purposes because, as noted in the post, MRP “is a useful tool, but potentially misleading
if used carelessly or indiscriminately.”
Ultimately, I suspect that trying to predict the detailed
results of elections in the multi-media age is going to become ever harder. As
information is thrown at us ever more rapidly, we will have to learn to
assimilate it more quickly, and our quantitative models will have to take on
board information from sources such as Twitter (already possible in statistical
packages such as R). I am sure that in the course of the next week, some bright
spark will ask me why I failed to get the election result right. The simple
answer is because it’s hard to do, so I leave it to those with the expertise, time
and resources to do it. And even they struggle, so what chance have I got?
After a slog of a campaign which broke the mould for both
the Conservatives and Labour, the election we didn’t need produced the result
that the Conservatives didn’t want; it will potentially change the thrust of
economic policy and may have far-reaching implications for Brexit negotiations.
Without necessarily having any truck for Labour, I must confess to some
satisfaction in seeing the Conservatives run aground on the Brexit issue.
Almost twelve months after the searing experience on that sunny Friday morning
of 24 June 2016, the hard-liners on the right-wing of the Conservative Party
who lied their way to victory on Brexit, were chastened by the message handed
to them by the electorate, whilst UKIP’s brief spell as a serious political
force was effectively terminated.
I have pointed out many times that the efforts by Theresa
May and the rest of the Conservative Party to interpret the Brexit vote as a
mandate for a hard Brexit were misguided. Their efforts to take ownership of
the issue, as if Brexit was a topic only for Conservatives, were way off. The
irony is that whilst the election was all about Brexit, it was not even the
most important issue of the campaign. Austerity policy was the big story and
Conservative efforts to smear Labour’s tax-and-spend policy largely fell on
deaf ears.
I have spent the last seven years trying to get people to understand
that a fiscal policy based solely on cutting spending is only half a policy. We
have witnessed a huge rolling back of the state in recent years, and a withdrawal
of the safety net which has genuinely left a lot of people with nowhere to
turn. Jeremy Corbyn’s message was that a country which forces its poorest
people to get by on charity was failing in its duty to its citizens. You do not
have to be a bleeding heart liberal to ask what happens to all the taxes we pay
if we have slashed the social welfare safety net so much. People clearly buy
into this and I suspect it is the reason why Labour made such gains at the
expense of the government.
But before we get too carried away, we should remember that
Labour did not win the election. They outperformed expectations, for sure, and
in the battle of the leaders came out on top. As in 1974, when Conservative
Prime Minister Edward Heath ran on the slogan “who runs Britain,” the
electorate has delivered an answer that politicians did not expect. All this
raises a question of whether politicians, particularly the government, really
are in tune with the public mood. Or are they lost in the bubble of focus
groups and Daily Mail headlines which do not paint a sufficiently accurate
picture? Past experience suggests that governments which lose touch make
mistakes, and they are usually punished at the ballot box.
The Conservatives were punished yesterday but escaped with serious,
rather than fatal, injuries – at least for now. They have to learn from those
mistakes. I have to confess I did not hear much contrition from Theresa May
last night. For an obviously intelligent woman, she needs to get with the
programme – for the sake of her career if nothing else. One of the more
enlightening interviews I heard overnight was given by former Cabinet Secretary
Lord Turnbull on the radio (here
7:48:25 into the recording) who was scathing about the way May has run her
government and accused her of running it as a “fiefdom” without the necessary
experience to manage the many tasks which modern governments need to take on.
In particular he was critical of the lack of economic expertise and directly
suggested that she was not up to the job of prime minister.
As a man of great experience at the heart of government,
Turnbull’s view should be taken seriously. In his view she is not the right
person to lead the country into Brexit negotiations and when asked whether she
should stand down, his response was “absolutely” – an extraordinary thing for a
man of his stature to say. At the very least, the prime minister will have to compromise
on the Brexit strategy. Turnbull pointed out that by entering into a coalition with the DUP,
the government should abandon the policy of leaving the EU Customs Union and
thereby resolve the Irish border problem, which is high on the list of things
the European Commission cares about.
If no such compromises are made, the UK will be driven ever
closer to the cliff edge that the prime minister has said she wishes to avoid.
And if we are pushed into that position, it will be an act of supreme economic
vandalism. I fear that the prime minister will not change course, as she is
fearful of the wrath of large swathes of her party if she does. But if she does
not, the electorate will also wreak its vengeance. Faced with these twin evils, I would be surprised if the prime minister lasts in office
much longer. As the hapless David Moyes found out when he succeeded Alex
Ferguson as Manchester United manager, sometimes the better strategy is to
avoid taking the top job under the wrong circumstances. Theresa May might have
been the least worst candidate for the job as prime minister last summer, but
it does not mean she is the best person for the job.
I was asked last week by the Sunday Telegraph to rank the
economic policies of Labour and the Conservative parties as part of a larger survey group. The story duly appeared under the heading “Economists back the Tories - but remain underwhelmed” in which it was suggested that while Dixon’s “criticism of the Tories centres
around their fixation on austerity, he is more scathing about Labour’s plans.”
Whilst I am grateful for the press coverage, and my comments were reported
accurately, I do believe they were given a spin which was not warranted by the
totality of my remarks. In the interests of balance, therefore, I reproduce
below the full transcript of my answers to the Telegraph’s survey.
Tax & spending
CON 3; LAB 3 (Marks out of 10 where 10 is good and 1 is
poor)
There are many good things about the Labour plans: (i) they are semi-costed so we
have some indication of how much they want to spend; (ii) There is also something to be said for establishing
a National Investment Bank even though it will not be able to generate the
£250bn in infrastructure spending that Labour plans. Far better to use it as a
conduit to fund SME lending as in Germany and the US, where the KfW and SBA
operate. The bad news (and the reason I
give the overall plan such low marks) is that too much emphasis is placed on
taxing higher earners and corporates. In other words, the tax base is too narrow.
For a party which seeks to promote equality, this is merely a “soak the rich
strategy” which will change the behaviour of those caught in the tax net. It is
thus unlikely to generate as much revenue as planned. In any case a penny on
the basic income tax rate yields 4x as much revenue as a penny on higher
earners. And whilst the idea of renationalising parts of the infrastructure
sounds attractive, this will result in as many problems as it solves. The
education pledge is too expensive given the
current numbers going into education. Abolishing university tuition fees
is a good thing, but it would have been more affordable 20-30 years ago.
However, Labour deserves credit for sparking a debate on the role of the state
in the economy.
This is more than can be said of the Conservatives, whose
economic manifesto offered nothing new. The commitment to balance the budget
only by the mid-2020s does raise a question of whether the austerity of the
last 7 years has been worthwhile. The public sector is creaking at the seams
and it is not in any position to withstand a further round of austerity. As the
Institute for Government has pointed out “the
Government is struggling to successfully implement the 2015 Spending review …
[with] clear signs of mounting pressures in public services.” A policy of
more austerity will be self-defeating and I would like to think that Philip
Hammond will take a less draconian
stance than George Osborne (the jury is out but his hands are tied by Brexit).
I maintain that the commitment to reducing corporate tax to 17% is a mistake
because it robs the Treasury of revenue and it is not as if HMRC is getting the
corporate tax receipts it already believes it is owed.
Immigration
CON: 3; LAB 5
The idea that we can get net immigration back to the tens of
thousands is economically illiterate and ultimately self-defeating although I
understand why the Conservatives made the pledge for political reasons.
However, targeting net immigration by focusing only on inflows, and continuing
to classify students in the numbers makes little sense. It remains to be seen
how a policy of “allowing us to attract the skilled workers our economy needs”
is compatible with the targets. Labour is vague on immigration although they
have sensibly resisted giving a pledge on numbers. The commitment to protecting
the rights of EU workers already in the UK will play well in Brussels.
Jobs & pay
CON: 2 ; LAB: 2
In this day and age, governments don’t really deliver jobs –
other than by setting overall conditions – and have little influence over pay,
except by controlling the minimum wage. Labour’s planned figure of £10/hour is
probably not unreasonable although it is a big stretch from where we are today
which will squeeze smaller businesses. The Conservative strategy which does not
give an outright figure, but plans 60% of the median wage, is probably less of
a hostage to fortune. The Conservatives are probably more realistic in the sense
that they did not talk about creating jobs but it is difficult to give marks to
either side because I am not convinced that they said very much, However, both
get credit for recognising worker rights though the Labour plans have a whiff
of the 1970s about them (“empower workers and their trade unions”).
Industrial strategy
CON: 6; LAB: 4
Both parties sound good on paper but there is little new
here. Both sides offer a tinkering at the margin approach – nobody would
dispute Labour’s view that we need to improve the economy’s skill levels but
this will take years to show any improvement and it was vague on how to achieve
it. The Labour manifesto had nothing substantive to say on productivity, which
is the UK’s Achilles Heel at present and the Conservatives score a little
higher, having already announced their National Productivity Investment Fund.
My concern, however, is that neither party will be able to do much in an
environment where global forces will play a major role (e.g. automation).
Social care & pensions
CON: 3; LAB: 5
The Conservatives scored an absolute own goal with their
initial plan on old age care provision, which was far less generous than that
scheduled to come into operation in 2020. It ignored the Dilnot Commission
proposal which advocated a cap on costs, thus mitigating against efforts to
create a market for insurance in this area. Although they have backtracked, the
damage is done. Sensible to remove the pension triple lock. Labour sound more
convincing on this issue but the problem is how to pay for it. They are relying
on squeezing higher earners and it is not clear whether they can afford all
their commitments given the demands from other areas.
Totting up the marks, that amounts to 17/50 for the
Conservatives and 19/50 for Labour (versus average marks of 23/50 for the Conservatives and 18/50 for Labour). Not exactly a ringing endorsement for
either party, as the headline suggested, but not enough in my case to suggest a bias towards the
Conservatives.
Although much of the current media attention is focused on
Donald Trump’s rather unfortunate comments in the wake of the latest London
terror attack, his decision last week to withdraw the US from the Paris
Agreement on climate change was a much bigger deal. To recap, the agreement was
drawn up in the first place in a bid to limit global greenhouse gas emissions
in order to curb the rise in global temperatures and thus prevent some of the
worst effects of climate change from causing even more environmental damage.
There are 195 signatories to the treaty, with only Syria, Nicaragua and the
Vatican not having signed up. However, the US decision to withdraw not only
drives a coach and horses through global cooperation efforts on climate change,
but it raises question marks against the commitment of the US to a whole range
of international agreements.
Turning first to the climate issues, I am not a climate
scientist so I am bound by the consensus of expert opinion which has done the
work and drawn the conclusions. What everyone agrees on is that the earth is
warming rapidly – global temperatures are around 2 degrees higher than when
measurement commenced in the late nineteenth century. We also know that the
amount of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere is at unprecedented levels (see
chart, courtesy of NASA).
The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) reckons that “anthropogenic greenhouse gas emissions … are
extremely likely to have been the dominant cause of the observed warming
since the mid-20th century.” Note that it does not say with 100%
probability that climate change is man-made, but “extremely likely” is the sort
of language scientists use when they are fairly sure. It may be that they are
wrong, but until such times as the world’s most reputable scientists change
their minds I’ll go with what they know, rather than what various interest
groups believe to be true. And even if the scientists are wrong, it is a better
insurance policy to take offsetting action rather than ignore them and find out
they were right.
The science of climate change also suggests that global
warming will have significant impacts on weather patterns, crop growing cycles,
access to water and has the potential to disrupt the way we live our lives (for
an overview of all these issues, see the Stern Review, which reported in 2006).
As Stern pointed out, climate change “entails costs that are not paid for by those who create the emissions …
Questions of intra- and inter-generational equity are central. Climate change
will have serious impacts within the lifetime of most of those alive today.
Future generations will be even more strongly affected, yet they lack
representation in present-day decisions.”
Trump’s decision is the ultimate in short-term thinking
designed to satisfy a tiny proportion of his country’s electorate whilst
ignoring the wider consequences for their children (viz the wonderful response by Emmanuel Macron to Trump’s decision).
Quite what better deal Trump has in mind for American workers by pulling out of
the agreement is hard to fathom. After all, there are fewer people employed in
coal mining in the US than in the green tech sector so it is not exactly a
rational response to domestic issues. It is also a wider abrogation of duty to
the rest of the planet, for as Stern also pointed out, solutions to the climate
change problem require a global response.
There is thus general agreement that Trump’s strategy is
self-defeating with regard to climate issues. But an equally serious concern is
that an America first strategy runs counter to the rules-based system which underpins
the world economic architecture and which has served the US so well for the
past 70 years. An America which does not adhere to the treaty commitments to
which it has signed up cannot expect others to play by the rules which the US
flagrantly ignores. It may “only” be climate change, the implications of which
will not become fully evident until after Trump is long gone, and in any case
the US can always sign up again under a different president. But can the US
expect all countries to adhere to the rules on global trade if for some reason
it does not suit them? To what extent can the US’s military allies in Asia or
Europe rely on its support?
International diplomacy is a game of give and take. Unfortunately,
Trump appears to see it as a game of winner takes all. Moreover, he has not yet
demonstrated that he understands the notion of cooperation on global issues
(not that the British government is in any position to cast aspersions). But if
Trump has any pretensions to providing leadership on a global scale, the
climate change policy needs to be rethought. Future generations of voters may
thank him for it.
As the UK election race unfolds, latest evidence continues
to point to the Conservatives winning next week’s ballot. However, the analysts at Electoral Calculus
currently reckon that their majority will come in at 74 seats compared to an
estimate of 168 three weeks ago (the current margin is 17). One poll released
earlier this week even indicated that the Tories might lose their overall
majority by winning fewer seats than they have now, although this was generally
dismissed as an outlier. But the shift in the polls has rattled the markets,
and foreign investors now see a risk that the election will not be the foregone
conclusion it seemed a few weeks ago (see chart).
As I noted back in April (was it really that long ago?) this
election is being fought purely for tactical reasons – and indeed the prime
minister admitted yesterday that the decision to call yet another plebiscite
was driven by Brexit-related reasons. In my view, this is nonsense. The rest of
the EU does not care how large the PM’s majority is: The UK will still be in a
minority of one in the Brexit negotiations. But the size of the majority
matters for May herself. A parliamentary majority around 50 (still decent,
let’s not forget) would be seen as the equivalent of a draw. Anything less would
put the PM in a difficult position as she has to deal with the right-wing of
her party, which has a habit of making life difficult for Conservative prime
ministers. In effect, she needs a big win to give her a personal mandate.
So why are the polls narrowing? It can simply be boiled down
to two factors: personality and policies. As George Parker wrote in the
Financial Times today, “Theresa May thought a snap election
would empower her, but what started in April as a quest for a “strong mandate”
to deliver Brexit is threatening to leave her diminished. Polls suggest the
more people see of her, the less popular she becomes.” Her main opponent,
Jeremy Corbyn, started out as a no-hoper who couldn’t be trusted to run a bath,
let alone the country, yet he is the one who has looked at ease in dealing with
the hostile questioning (the odd brain fade during interviews notwithstanding).
Corbyn has had to deal with questions about his past support for terrorist
organisations and his willingness to press the nuclear trigger in the event it
becomes necessary, and all-in-all has come out of it rather better than most
people expected. This does not make him prime minister-in-waiting, however.
Corbyn has spent the whole of his parliamentary career (34 years) opposing the
mainstream of his party on most key issues. He will struggle to find sufficient
MPs loyal to him in the unlikely event he becomes PM.
So if the personalities are not very appealing, we must
judge them on their policies. Here again, both sides are found wanting. In
summary, the Conservatives propose too much austerity and Labour promises too much tax-and-spend. Neither has talked enough about the single
biggest issue facing the UK during the next parliamentary term – Brexit.
Indeed, the prime minister seems to be asking the electorate merely to trust that
she will “deliver the best deal for Britain.” That is not good enough. I would
be more inclined to listen to a politician who acknowledges what economists
have been saying for the last four years, that Brexit comes with a cost – a big
one – and that they have a plan to deal with it. A party which proposes that
“no deal is better than a bad deal” does not cut it.
Meanwhile, Labour’s tax-and-spend policy is open to the
criticism levied by Conservative politicians that “there isn’t a magic money
tree” to fund their plans. This is, of course, spot on although if I were
Jeremy Corbyn, I would be pointing out that senior Conservative politicians
such as the Foreign Secretary only twelve months ago supported the idea that
leaving the EU would immediately mean that the UK could devote an additional
£350m per week to the NHS. The manifesto
analysis conducted by the IFS last week provided a pretty damning assessment of the fiscal plans of both sides arguing
that “neither sets out an honest set of
choices.” Though as an aside, I found this blog piece
by John Weeks an interesting insight into the shortcomings of the IFS’s
analysis.
As we head towards polling day, I get the sense that many
people are unenthused by the choices on offer. I almost have feelings of
nostalgia for Screaming Lord Sutch and his Monster Raving Loony Party.
Unlike Lord Sutch, the MRLP is still with us, however, and amongst their
manifesto (or as they call it, manicfesto) commitments for 2017 are a pledge to
“nationalise crime to make sure it
doesn’t pay,” “reducing the alphabet
to 23 characters. This will start by cutting the letters N. H. and S” and
giving atheism charitable status on the grounds that it is a “non-prophet organization.” I’ve heard
worse.