Tuesday 18 February 2020

Frost in Brussels

I am far from sure whether yesterday’s keynote speech in Brussels by David Frost, Boris Johnson’s policy adviser on Europe, was an opening gambit in what is likely to be a long and bitter negotiation between the UK and EU or was really the statement of intent it was made out to be. It was provocative, as might be expected from one who is a self-confessed supporter of Brexit as he made it clear that the UK will not accept supervision from the EU as part of a post-Brexit free trade deal. Worse still, Frost airily dismissed the economics with an “it will be all right in the end” attitude, without putting forward any evidence to support his claims. Perhaps it’s all an act or maybe he really has no idea what he is talking about. But if this is to be the tone of the British government’s approach to Brexit throughout 2020, it is going to be a long, hard year.

Frost’s attempt to rationalise Brexit

Frost’s justification for Brexit leaned heavily on the work of Edmund Burke who, despite being “one of my country’s great political philosophers”, was born and raised in Dublin where he spent the first 21 years of his life. Burke was a student of the French Revolution and one of his most famous works, Reflections on the Revolution in France, argued that the revolution would end in failure because its foundation on the abstract notion of rationality ignored the complexities of human nature and the institutions which were built around it. Academics struggle to interpret this work. This paper by David Armitage notes that there is ongoing debate about whether Burke “was a realist or an idealist, a Rationalist or a Revolutionist.” Frost chooses to interpret him as a realist by invoking the premise that the formation of the EU constitutes a revolution in European governance which overrides national institutions serving the people of individual countries. But whilst Frost’s view of a monolithic EU has some foundation, his interpretation is not one I recognise.

He argues that “if you can’t change policies by voting, as you increasingly can’t in this situation –  then opposition becomes expressed as opposition to the system itself.” But this is to ignore the fact that whilst EU laws are drafted by the Commission, they are passed into law by the European Parliament – comprised of the MEPs we vote for. And whilst it may be true that “the key [EU] texts are as hard to read for the average citizen as the Latin Bible was at the time of Charles the Bold” I can attest that British laws are equally hard to understand for non-lawyers such as myself. After all, I have (tried to) read a lot more British law in the last two years than is good for me.

Where Frost does have a point is that European institutions are, in British eyes, “more abstract, they were more technocratic.” There is not the drama associated with the European Parliament that is associated with Westminster, but as the lessons of the last twelve months have shown that is not necessarily a bad thing. Where I do not agree is the coda to the sentence in which he states European institutions “were more disconnected from or indeed actively hostile to national feeling.” They were perceived as hostile to national interests, it is true, but that is largely thanks to the disinformation (or lies, if you will) pumped out by journalists like Boris Johnson during his time in Brussels.

Nor am I convinced by Frost’s simplistic argument that “Brexit was surely above all a revolt against a system” where “the system” was the EU. “I don’t think it is right to dismiss this just as a reaction to austerity or economic problems” may be his view but not one necessarily backed up by the evidence. The Leave campaign made all sorts of promises that they could not deliver about the benefits of Brexit and the issues were simply too complex to be boiled down into a “yes/no” question, as even my Leave-supporting friends admit. Frost makes the mistake of drawing inferences about the 2016 vote which were not evident at the time. For an eminently clever man, Frost’s arguments were little more than a weak post-hoc justification. And if I can see that, you can bet that the smart people in the EU Commission will come to a similar conclusion. But if the justification for Brexit was weak, wait until you hear his economic arguments.

Trying to justify the economics

Frankly, the economics did not even rate a D+. His opening gambit was to dismiss the work done by the UK Government and the BoE thus: “I would question some of the specifics of all those studies. This probably isn’t the moment to go into the detail … But, in brief, all these studies exaggerate – in my view – the impact of non-tariff barriers.” Try that in an undergraduate essay and see how far you get. To apply the Farage tactic (“I could be more specific about my objections but now is not the time”) is not good enough. Economists are not interested in his view – they want the evidence that contradicts their own. Indeed, the evidence suggests that non-tariff barriers can be more restrictive for trade than actual tariffs. Simple things like technical barriers to trade (regulations on the content of products) or inspections and other formalities that require goods are checked for various reasons are pretty hard to get around. Indeed, there is a well-established literature on the empirical costs of border effects[1].

He went on to note that “many Brexit studies seem very keen to ignore or minimise any of the upsides, whether these be connected to expanded trade with the rest of the world or regulatory change.” There is a reason for that: With the exception of Patrick Minford, whose “analysis” is not worth the time of day, I struggle to think of any study which points to a net economic benefit from Brexit. Similarly, “there is obviously a one-off cost from the introduction of friction at a customs and regulatory border, but I am simply not convinced it is on anything like the scale or with the effects these studies suggest.” But that’s the sort of reasoning used by those who believe the Earth is flat: “Because I cannot see the curvature I am simply not convinced it is anything but flat.”

Ultimately, this speech contained nothing to convince any of us who believe the economic costs of Brexit are non-trivial that the government can be trusted to look after the interests of the economy. Frost made it clear that “we are ready to trade on Australia-style terms if we can’t agree a Canada type FTA”. Since Australia has not yet signed a trade deal with the EU he means the UK is prepared to trade on WTO terms at a time when the WTO has ceased to function properly. But it gets worse. “We understand the trade-offs involved – people sometimes say we don’t but we do … Much of the debate about will Britain diverge from the EU I think misses this point. … But it is perfectly possible to have high standards, and indeed similar or better standards to those prevailing in the EU, without our laws and regulations necessarily doing exactly the same thing … I struggle to see why this is so controversial.” That last line sums it up. The British government either does not understand the EU’s position or chooses not to do so. If you want to have access to the club, you simply have to abide by the rules. This is not a matter for debate.

The galling thing about the whole speech is that it echoes the tone of Theresa May at her worst. It was similarly content-light, promoted a revisionist version of history and made promises which will be undeliverable if the EU refuses to bend. Johnson will run into the same problem as his predecessor. Obviously both sides have to sound tough at the start of negotiations but it really does not have to be like this. What concerns me most is that if this really does represent the UK government’s position, we are headed for a major clash before the year is out. And despite what anyone else may say to the contrary, a hard Brexit is most emphatically not what people voted for in 2016. It’s going to be a rough ride. 


[1] Anderson, J.E., E. van Wincoop (2003) ‘Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle’, The American Economic Review 93 (1), 170–192

No comments:

Post a Comment