Friday 29 December 2017

Generating economic policy buy-in


Just before Christmas, the FT commentator Gideon Rachman penned a column which argued very strongly that “Economics is – or should be – part of moral philosophy  …  ‘the economy’ is not just about growth. It is also about justice.” This is a very important point and one that tends to be overlooked, or at least downplayed, by large parts of the economics profession. Rachman argues – as indeed as I have done on this blog – that many voters do not buy into the economic vision offered by politicians because they do not see how it benefits them. What is even worse, they often believe they are being discriminated against in favour of other interest groups.

Making America great again speaks to the millions of voters who believe somehow that the US’s status of top dog is being eroded by emerging economies that do not play by the economic rules and that the US is being penalised for abiding by them. In a similar vein, taking back control speaks to those British voters who see the UK as being held back by a monolithic EU. As an economist, I find such statements absurd. After all, the US is still the pre-eminent economic and military superpower whilst EU membership gives the UK access to the largest and richest single market on the planet. But there is no reason why this should cut any ice with the average voter who is struggling to make ends meet at a time of low wage inflation and against a perceived backdrop of mounting job insecurity (which incidentally is not backed up by the UK evidence).

The predominant economic model in the Anglo Saxon world over the last 35 years has been a market-oriented policy in which government has tried to reduce its role in the belief that the market will provide the most efficient allocation of resources, thus boosting welfare. Prior to 2008 the evidence appeared to suggest that whilst voters were aware of the downsides of this model, the economic tide was rising sufficiently quickly to float all boats. But political and economic circumstances have changed over the past decade. Society’s sense of natural justice was offended by government actions to bail out banks whilst simultaneously imposing a policy of fiscal austerity, which sowed the seeds of a belief that the system is rigged in favour of big business at the expense of the little guy.

This has resulted in many aspects of our current model being put under the microscope and raises questions whether economic policy is going in the direction which voters are prepared to buy into. As Rachman points out, intra-generational issues are uppermost in the minds of many voters. There are concerns across the western economies that those in born after 1980 will not be as wealthy as their parents. Evidence from the UK, for example, suggests that younger adults have much less wealth to their name than previous generations did at a similar age. Over the past decade, as younger voters have gone through university and entered the labour force, many of them are beginning to question whether they will be able to reap the economic rewards they were promised. UK students no longer get the benefit of a free university education and finish their university studies with much higher levels of debt than their parents. Indeed, UK students now carry a staggering £13bn of debt – an increase of almost 190 times what they owed in 1990.

At the same time, the younger generation must pay the taxes to cover the rising costs of providing for the welfare needs of the ageing baby boomers, whilst struggling to find the high-paying jobs which previous generations were able to secure. They will also have to deal with the fallout from the populist reactions triggered by the Brexit vote and the election of Trump – both of which were propelled by the votes of the older generation. Millennials in the industrialised world can be forgiven for questioning the legacy bequeathed to them by older generations.

Policies which offer a trade-off between more market solutions and lower taxes are increasingly unlikely to find electoral favour. Nobody wants to pay more taxes, of course, but there are limits on how far countries such as the UK can continue to reduce them and still maintain the reasonable standard of public services that the public has come to expect. Scarcely a week goes by without a newspaper story decrying cuts to the armed forces or the strains imposed on a health system which struggles to cope with the strains placed upon it. It is perhaps for this reason that we are seeing renewed voter interest in “radical left” parties across Europe which promise a greater role for the state in a bid to improve the lot of those left behind (chart).

Indeed, as the IMF pointed out last week in its regular assessment of the UK economygreater reliance on revenue measures for [fiscal] consolidation than in recent years may be warranted.” Amongst the potential measures put forward were a reduction in “the tax code’s bias toward debt” which benefits corporations, and rebalancing property taxation away from transactions and toward property values. Ironically, the US appears to have gone in the other direction with the recently unveiled changes to the tax system primarily benefiting corporates and better off individuals.

If we really are in it together (to use George Osborne’s phrase) some changes to the incidence of taxation would be a good place to start to help win over voters that the system is not biased against them. Whilst many in the policy establishment draw on the laissez-faire teachings of Adam Smith, we should not forget that “The Theory of Moral Sentiments” extensively explored ideas such as morality and human sympathy. He never advocated the devil-take-the-hindmost policy which many of his adherents claim. It is a lesson the economic and policy establishment perhaps needs to relearn.

No comments:

Post a Comment