Wednesday 13 December 2017

Central banks and the digital currency revolution


In previous posts, I have argued that Bitcoin is a bubble which looks destined to burst. But bubble or no, the ideas underpinning digital currencies have piqued the interest of central banks which are aware of their potential. There are many reasons why they are interested in the digital currency revolution. For one thing, if such currencies take off as a medium of exchange, they will erode the traditional central bank monopoly over monetary issuance which in turn would reduce their control over the economy. As a result, there is an incentive for central banks to get involved if for no other reason than to head off the threat posed by private digital currencies.

Another argument in favour of a digital currency is that transactions using blockchain technology are transparent and traceable which would reduce the scope for tax evasion and illegal activity. In addition, it allows a greater degree of policy flexibility when interest rates are at the lower bound. In short, if we separate the unit of account function of money from its other functions by creating a parallel currency, it is possible to set an exchange rate between paper money and electronic money. By allowing paper money to depreciate (i.e. offering fewer units in exchange for the electronic alternative) this reduces the incentive to hold paper. In an environment where electronic currency is the dominant form, central banks have more flexibility to reduce the interest rate on deposits which does not exist in a paper cash economy. In a paper money world, if banks charge negative rates on deposits, individuals need only switch to zero interest bearing cash to avoid the negative charges.

This possibility is not available in an environment where digital currency is the only option: Account holders would have to store it in some other asset outside of central bank control.
In order for such a system to work relies on adapting a blockchain, or electronic digital ledger, which can be controlled centrally rather than relying on the distributed ledger technology currently employed by Bitcoin. As it currently stands, blockchain relies explicitly on a community of mutually distrustful parties to ensure that transactions are recorded correctly. Precisely because nobody trusts anybody else, no single individual or entity controls the digital record. Instead, the settlement technology relies on an encryption system to ensure that all users have access to the ledger simultaneously and each of them can update it. But the form of blockchain used to generate Bitcoin suffers from a number of technical limitations which will preclude the wider use of this particular digital currency.

For one thing, it can only process a relatively small number of transactions. The Bitcoin network can currently only process 7 transactions per second (tps) whereas the credit card Visa has a peak capacity of 56,000 tps and handles 2,000 tps on average. For a currency with aspirations to widespread acceptance this is a huge limitation, and is one of the reasons why I continue to believe that the upside for Bitcoin is limited. The obvious solution to the Bitcoin problem is to raise the size of the data blocks (currently, their size is limited to one megabyte which takes 10 minutes to process). Efforts to get all the Bitcoin miners to agree an increase in the size of the blocks has proved extremely difficult with the result that the blockchain has split once already this year, with one group opting to remain on the current standard and the others going off to form a parallel digital currency with fewer such technical constraints. Ironically, the Bitcoin system was initially designed to run at twice its current speed but it was limited for security reasons.

Indeed, security concerns may well be one of the issues which undermine Bitcoin. In theory, so long as no miner can control more than 50% of the network, they are unable to falsify the chain. But there have been well-publicised instances where Bitcoin exchanges have been hacked so it is clearly not as safe as its proponents believe. Moreover, if one individual or a colluding group of miners is able to gain more than 50% of the total network computing power they will technically be able to force a break in the chain, allowing them to override the rest of the community and take over the chain. Raising the size of the blocks in the chain could inadvertently lead to such an outcome. Miners with access to huge computing power and very low energy costs would be better placed to afford more bandwidth, which may lead to a higher concentration of miners.


So where do central banks come in? One possibility is that they create a centralised digitally encrypted record which would get around the security problems in the current system, Indeed, the system on which Bitcoin is based operates very much like the wild west – if there is a problem you are on your own, as there is no-one to turn to. By acting as the guarantor of the system, central banks eliminate this problem. In such a system, it is envisaged that individuals would hold a digital wallet at the central bank, with their incentive to do so enhanced by the differential rates of return offered on digital and paper money, outlined above.


But what happens to commercial banks in a system where the central bank manages the transactions and creates the digital currency? One possibility might be that banks create their own digital currency which can be exchanged for the central bank unit at a given rate. This would allow banks to create credit in the same way they do now whilst giving central banks the ability to control the overall rate of credit creation by altering the digital currency exchange rate.


Other alternative central bank currency models appear to ignore the commercial banking system altogether, relegating them to the role of transaction processors. In such a world, banks manage a number of lower-level chains which record transactions, and which in turn feed into the main ledger to which only the central bank has the digital key. Essentially, banks would become transaction verifiers rather than account holders. Since the costs of becoming a transaction verifier are far smaller than operating a fully-fledged bank, this might be expected to raise banking competition as new entrants come into the market which will reduce the costs of banking for the wider public.

We are obviously a long way from being able to introduce this kind of system. But it does suggest that the theoretical possibilities of a digital currency system are far greater than the relatively narrow range of outcomes offered by Bitcoin. This is one of the key reasons why we should not dismiss the digital currency story. However, it does not always pay to have first mover advantage. Recall that the mid-1970s Betamax technology, which was many people’s introduction to home video, was quickly supplanted by the technologically inferior VHS system, which in turn gave way to the DVD revolution. Home video was once a big deal, but who remembers Betamax today? We could be saying the same thing about Bitcoin in the years to come.

No comments:

Post a Comment