With interest rates trapped at the lower bound central
banks have in recent years adopted a policy of forward guidance to help markets
interpret what they were likely to do in the face of the incoming data flow. Its
success has been mixed. Recall the bond market “taper tantrum” in 2013 when the
Federal Reserve announced that it was about to slow down the pace of asset
purchases - though in fairness, this was more the result of a market which
panicked rather than the fault of the central bank. But so far this year the Fed has
more or less adhered to the message contained in the dot plot (see p3 here)
despite the market’s initial scepticism.
Arguably, the Bank of England’s efforts at forward guidance
have not been quite as successful, and in a week of important UK data releases
which may determine whether the BoE will soon raise rates, it is important to
understand the nature of the forward guidance message. In August 2013 the BoE
pledged “not to raise Bank Rate from its
current level of 0.5% at least until … the unemployment rate has fallen to a
threshold of 7%.” The BoE was clear that this was a conditional target,
subject to (i) CPI inflation 18 to 24 months ahead no more than 0.5 percentage
points above the 2% target; (ii) medium-term inflation expectations no longer
remaining sufficiently well anchored and (iii) the stance of monetary policy
posing a significant threat to financial stability. Even though unemployment
fell more rapidly than the BoE – and indeed, most other forecasters –
anticipated, none of the knockouts were ever triggered. Thus although policy
was conditional, it was never fully clear why the BoE did not raise rates once
the unemployment rate fell below 7%. Good arguments could be made for leaving
rates on hold but it rather defeated the purpose of the forward guidance
framework.
By February 2014 the BoE abandoned the simple mechanistic
link between monetary policy and unemployment in favour of a less easily defined
policy based on the nebulous concept of spare capacity. Since the measure of
spare capacity was determined by the BoE, this meant that outside observers
became increasingly reliant on the information feed from the MPC to determine
the future policy stance. The clarity of rule-based forward guidance policy was
lost. Later in 2014, at his Mansion House speech, Governor Carney suggested
that the first rise in interest rates “could
happen sooner than markets currently expect.” It didn’t. And to this day it
is difficult to explain why the rate hike did not happen other than the fact
that the BoE simply did not want to act before the Fed.
Last month “a majority
of MPC members judged that, if the economy continued to follow a path
consistent with the prospect of a continued erosion of slack and a gradual rise
in underlying inflationary pressure then, with the further lessening in the
trade-off that this would imply, some withdrawal of monetary stimulus was
likely to be appropriate over the coming months.” We know from this morning’s
parliamentary testimony that two Committee members (Dave Ramsden and Silvana
Tenreyro) are not part of that majority. We also know that four other members appear
to be edging towards an earlier rate increase whilst the view of the other three
is unknown.
Arguably, given the clarity of the message given in recent weeks,
the MPC needs to deliver sooner rather than later after having left markets
hanging in the past. Of course, “coming months” does not necessarily refer to November
(the next month in which an Inflation Report is released) – it could just as
easily be February (the following Inflation Report month). But the fact that
little has been done to dissuade the market of this view suggests that November
would be a good time to act. Leaving the door open until February runs the risk
that events could transpire which change the Bank’s priorities, and despite the
conditional nature of the policy decision, markets will see this as another occasion
on which it has cried wolf.
Policy credibility remains important to policymakers. An
absence of such credibility defeats the purpose of forward guidance. Whilst the
BoE can justifiably argue that forward guidance is conditional on economic
circumstances, it cannot continue to hide behind the Augustinian clause forever
(allow us to raise interest rates, but not just yet). Whether or not it is the
right time to consider a rate increase is almost irrelevant – my own view is
that the recent surge which has taken CPI inflation to 3% is not a good
justification for a policy tightening, driven as it is by a one-off sterling
depreciation. However, what matters is the consistency of the message. The
markets are hearing a very clear message: It would require a lot of explanation
on the BoE’s part if it were to pass up on a rate hiking opportunity.
No comments:
Post a Comment