But what is the point of all this communication? Central
banks in democratic societies believe that they have a duty to get their
message across to as many citizens as possible. There is a certain logic to this:
After all, even though most central banks are independent – albeit to varying
degrees – they still have a duty to explain their actions to the people in
whose name they are acting. One of the pioneers of such communications
was the Bank of Canada in the 1950s whose governor, James Coyne, viewed BoC
speeches and other reports as devices to explain monetary policy to the public
but also as a tool to underpin the central bank’s credibility and reputation.
Karl Blessing, President of the Bundesbank from 1958 to 1969, similarly argued
that: “A central bank which never fights,
which at times of economic tension never raises its voice ... will be viewed
with mistrust.”
Of course, much of this effort is wasted if those at whom
the information is aimed do not understand the message being conveyed. The BoE
is acutely aware of this problem and it was highlighted in a post by Jon
Fullwood on the Bank Underground blog last October (here)
which demonstrated that BoE texts generally have a Grade 14 reading level,
which is equivalent to that required by a second year university student. In
any case, even if the message is understood, it may not be accepted –
particularly at a time when trust in institutions is low. This raises an
important question of whether trust and understanding are inextricably linked.
It is likely, as Haldane points out, that
“change in the nature of public
language – shorter, simpler, shriller – puts an even greater premium on
institutions making themselves understood … That means speaking in words and
sentences that land rather than levitate with the public, that connect rather
than divide public opinion, that illuminate rather than darken public debate.”
Some might say that this is akin to dumbing down the
message. But there is nothing wrong with a little dumbing down if it gets the
message across – after all, those with more interest in the subject matter can
always engage at a higher level if they have the desire to do so. In any case,
the actions of managing the economy do not have to change at all – merely the
way in which they are communicated. Central bank communication can, of course,
be taken to extremes as Richmond Fed President Jeff Lacker found out this week
following the discovery that he had communicated sensitive market information
to an analyst (prompting his immediate resignation). Sometimes the phrase “too
much information” takes on a new meaning.
But despite central bank efforts to ensure that they
communicate as effectively as possible, sometimes I wonder whether they overdo
it. Should central banks worry overly much about whether their every last
utterance is understood by the ordinary citizen? A certain degree of financial
literacy amongst the general public is desirable but many citizens manage just
fine without much knowledge about what central banks are up to.
As for a market perspective, it sometimes feels like Say’s
Law is in operation, with supply creating its own demand. In other words, the
more information central banks give out, the more markets seem to want. I would
not be at all surprised if at some point in the near future there are calls for
live broadcasts of central bank discussions, or at the least a live Twitter
feed. That said markets are much more trusting of central banks today.
Gone are the days when markets used to interpret central bank actions as being
motivated by any informational advantage which they enjoyed. This is partly the
result of greater central bank openness – after all, the Fed has gone out of
its way to avoid a repeat of the actions which prompted the bond crash of 1994.
But it is also to do with the communications revolution which means that
markets and central banks operate with similar information sets.
Ironically, economists were originally employed in financial
markets to interpret the actions of opaque central banks. I well remember a TV
interview around 1990 in which Gavyn Davies was asked what the 1990s would hold
for the City. His answer was something to the effect that he did not know but
he ventured that by the end of the decade there would be fewer economists
employed than there were at that time. He was wrong about that: But with central
banks providing much more information and comment than they used to, it is
possible that he will only be wrong about the timing.
No comments:
Post a Comment