Monday, 29 April 2019

The market for central bank governors

The search for a successor to BoE Governor Carney kicked off last week, ahead of his contract expiry next January, whilst jockeying for the top job at the ECB has also got underway with Mario Draghi due to stand down in November. Naturally the press has had a field day looking at the possible candidates for both positions. But less attention has been paid to the qualities necessary to be an effective central bank governor.

Over the last 30 years there has been a tendency to appoint economists to the top job. It has not always been the case, of course. Whilst former ECB President Trichet and BoE Governor Eddie George both had academic qualifications in the subject, neither would be regarded as front-line economists. But compare them to contemporaries such as Alan Greenspan, Ben Bernanke, Janet Yellen, Wim Duisenberg, Mervyn King and Draghi it is clear that a strong economics background has been viewed as an advantage. The reason for this is simple enough: Over recent years, central banks have been given a mandate to target inflation which means that they have a much closer focus on economic issues than has historically been the case.

However, I do wonder whether the unwillingness to raise interest rates – particularly in Europe – reflects the overly cautious nature of a policy-making body in which economists hold the upper hand. It was not for nothing that President Harry Truman reputedly demanded a one-handed economist in order to eliminate their tendency to say “on the one hand … but on the other.” More seriously, since the financial crisis central banks have acquired additional responsibility to manage the stability of the financial system which means that a macroeconomic background may not be the advantage that it once was.

Perhaps the most important job of any CEO, whether of a central bank or a listed company, is institution building. Mark Carney promised to be the new broom at the BoE who would bring the bank into the 21st century, getting rid of many of the arcane practices which had become institutionalised over the years and improving diversity. I am not qualified to say whether he has succeeded in this goal but we hear good things about the working environment within the central bank. More importantly, perhaps, the BoE has taken on the regulation and supervision of around 1500 financial institutions over the past six years as the responsibilities of the central bank have evolved and the head of the Prudential Regulation Authority occupies one of the most senior jobs in the BoE.

One of those touted to succeed Carney is Andrew Bailey, head of the Financial Conduct Authority, an institution independent of the BoE which is charged with ensuring that “financial markets work well so that consumers get a fair deal.” Bailey is a former BoE official who has worked in an economics function, but crucially has a very strong background in regulation. It is an indication of the extent to which the BoE’s role has changed in recent years that Bailey is even in the running for the job.

The experience of the ECB President has been rather different since Mario Draghi took over in 2011. He is – probably rightly – credited with holding the European single currency bloc together during the Greek debt crisis by promising to do “whatever it takes,” despite opposition from representatives of other member states, notably Germany. Like the BoE, the ECB has also taken on greater responsibility for the regulation of financial institutions although unlike the BoE there is no suggestion that the potential successor to Draghi will need a background in financial regulation.

Interestingly, this paper by Prachi Mishra and Ariell Reshef makes the point that the personal characteristics and experience of central bank governors does affect financial regulation. “In particular, experience in the financial sector is associated with greater financial deregulation [whilst] experience in the United Nations and in the Bank of International Settlements is associated with less deregulation.” They go on to argue that their analysis “strengthen[s] the importance of considering the background and past work experience before appointing a governor.”

This is an important point. In 2012, when the BoE was looking for a successor to Mervyn King, the Chancellor of the Exchequer cast his net far and wide. Mark Carney got the gig because the government wanted an outsider to take over a central bank which was perceived to be too close to the institutions it was meant to regulate. Moreover, he had previous experience of running a central bank. But whilst Carney has done a good job over the past six years, I still believe it wrong to think (as the Chancellor George Osborne did during the hiring process) that filling this role is akin to finding a CEO of a multinational company, whose place can be filled by anyone from an (allegedly) small pool of international talent. They are an unelected official who holds a position of key strategic importance, enjoying unprecedented powers to influence both monetary policy and the shape of the banking system. In that sense it has never been clear to me that the interests of an outsider with no experience of UK policy issues are necessarily aligned with the UK's national interest.

Contrast this with the way the ECB process works. There are, in theory, 19 candidates for the top job amongst the central bank governors of EMU members, all of whose interests are aligned with those of the euro zone. In addition, there are another five potential candidates amongst the members of the Executive Board. Admittedly there is a lot of political horse-trading involved in the selection process, but there is no need to look for an outsider who may not necessarily be up to speed with the complexities of local issues, not to mention local politics which is increasingly a problem for central bankers (I will come back to this another time).

For the record, this is absolutely not an issue of economic nationalism – it is simply to remind those making hiring decisions that just because someone has done a similar job does not necessarily make them the best candidate for a position elsewhere. Indeed, if the evidence from the private sector is anything to go by, the continuity candidate may be the best person for the job: In the private sector, “firms relying on internal CEOs have on average higher profits than external-CEO firms”. And for anyone who doubts that the search for an external candidate will necessarily be an improvement over the local options, just ask the English Football Association about their experiences with Sven-Göran Eriksson and Fabio Capello.

No comments:

Post a Comment