A few months back I produced a piece which looked at the
economics of the World Cup. The fun part of the analysis was to look at the
expected performance of each team based on a number of factors. Using a
statistical model, based on the Poisson distribution which took account of the
strength of each team and the quality of the opposition, I came up with a
ranking that was pretty close to that of the bookmakers. The bit that everyone
focused on, of course, was the tip for the tournament. As it happened, my
statistical model made Germany favourites to win, but as we all now know
Germany failed to qualify from the group stage.
Of course, the press gleefully highlighted the prediction error
– as they did with all those who failed to correctly predict the winner. The
only thing was, I didn’t really get it wrong. Although I made Germany the most
likely team to win, I only assigned an 18% probability to their chances of
tournament success, implying an 82% chance of not winning. In bookmakers’
parlance, I put the odds against Germany winning the tournament at 4-1. Sure
enough, Germany did not win the tournament – the most likely outcome predicted
by the model.
The idea that we apply probabilistic assessments to outcomes
strikes me as a sensible way to think about an inherently unknowable future and
it is a point I have made on numerous occasions previously (here,
for example). At a time when macroeconomics has come in for considerable
criticism for its failure to accurately forecast future events, understanding
the process of how forecasts are made is worthy of further investigation.
Critical to understanding the nature of an economic forecast
is that they are heavily conditional. In fact everything in economics depends
on everything else, so if some of the conditioning factors change the forecast
is likely to be blown off course. Consider the case of forecasting how a
central bank might set interest rates on the basis that it follows an inflation
targeting regime. We assume that inflation is a function of the amount of spare
capacity in the economy – the less slack there is, the more competition for
resources which then bids up their price. The choice of model itself is a major
conditioning factor. If central banks use different metrics in making their
decision, this raises the chance that the forecast will be wrong.
But let us pursue our assumption a bit further: In order to
determine how much slack there is in the economy, we have to understand trends
on both the demand and supply side which introduces additional conditioning
factors. On the demand side we need to know what is the likely path of driving
forces such as incomes, taxes (which influence disposable incomes and labour
supply decisions) and wealth (which can be used to finance consumption and
which also impacts on desired saving levels). On the supply side, we need to
know something about changes in the capital stock, which requires assumptions
for investment and the rate of capital depreciation; the size of the labour
force and the path of multifactor productivity. It should be pretty obvious by
now that in a short space of time, we have identified a whole chain of events
which could impact at any point to change our assessment of the amount of spare
capacity and thus the potential inflationary threat.
It is pretty unlikely that we are going to predict all the
inputs correctly, with the result that there is a considerable margin of
uncertainty associated with our projections. When the economy is subject to an
exogenous shock, such as in the wake of the Lehman’s bust or Brexit, the degree
of uncertainty is significantly raised. Consider the UK in the wake of the
Brexit vote: There was no effective government following David Cameron’s
resignation and it was totally unclear whether the UK would invoke Article 50
in June 2016, as some had advocated. In this vacuum of uncertainty, large
forecasting errors were made in the immediate post-referendum environment.
But contrary to the statements made by a number of
pro-Brexit politicians about how the doomsayers were wrong before the referendum, much of what the forecasting profession said
has stood up to scrutiny. Notably that the pound would collapse, inflation
would rise and the economy would grow more slowly and thus suffer a loss of
output relative to the case of no vote for Brexit. Obviously we don’t know what
will happen from here because we do not yet know the nature of the UK’s future
trading arrangements with the EU. One way to proceed is to outline a number of
scenarios and assess what might happen to growth in each case. If we assign a
probability to each scenario then our best guess for output growth is the
probability-weighted average of the outcomes.
But how useful is the single point estimate for annual
growth over the next five years in the case of Brexit? The answer, I suspect,
is not much. We are more interested in the cost of our forecast being wrong (i.e.
whether we are too optimistic or pessimistic relative to the outturn). We thus
should focus on the loss function, which measures the cost of being wrong. This
is not something that gets the attention it perhaps deserves because it can be
a costly and time-consuming exercise. Instead we generally define a range of
forecast extremes which encompass a median (or modal) forecast. The extent to
which this forecast lies in the upper or lower half of the range determines the
extent to which forecast risks are asymmetric, giving us some idea of the costs
of being too optimistic versus being overly pessimistic.The Bank of England has long been an advocate of this approach (see chart, which assesses the range of outcomes for the August 2018 inflation forecast).
My efforts at forecasting future economic events are guided
by Niels Bohr’s quip that “prediction is very difficult, especially if it's
about the future.” Experience has taught me that we should treat our central
case economic predictions as the most likely of a range of possibilities, and
nothing more. After all, there is no certainty. When Germany can
underperform so spectacularly on the international football stage, even the
most confident of forecasters should take note.
No comments:
Post a Comment