The issue of digital currencies has been bubbling away for a
few years, even after the initial hype surrounding Bitcoin dissipated in early
2018. I wrote a series of posts in late-2017 pointing out that the Bitcoin rally was unlikely to be sustained. Nonetheless,
it has not collapsed into oblivion as I feared possible. Indeed, over the last
15 months the price of Bitcoin relative to the US dollar has traded around the
levels which prevailed immediately prior to the peak of the boom in December
2017 (chart). The announcement last year that Facebook was behind a proposal to
introduce Libra has given new impetus to the concept of digital currencies, whilst one of the
side effects of the current social distancing regime is that many retailers prefer electronic payment rather than handling physical cash.
There are in essence two proposed types of digital currency
– one which is operated by the private sector free from central bank
interference, whilst the counter proposal is that central banks should engage
in this area themselves. Recall that the original idea behind digital
currencies was to break away from a money creation process controlled by
governments and central banks which were perceived as having debased the value
of money by inflating its supply. It is thus ironic that central banks have
entered into the debate with increasing urgency in recent years. The cynics
argue that this is because the rise of a privately run digital currency would
rob central banks of their raison d'ĂȘtre. Central banks argue that the private
sector either cannot or will not provide the security that individuals demand
of the medium taking the place of physical cash and that it requires some form
of oversight to protect the interests of society.
In my view, central banks have not yet made a sufficiently convincing
case for the introduction of a digital currency under their control. In a paper issued last month,
for example, the Bank of England suggested that a central bank digital currency (CDBC) “could support a more resilient payments landscape. It also has the
potential to allow households and businesses to make fast, efficient and reliable
payments, and to benefit from an innovative, competitive and inclusive payment
system. It could help to meet future payments needs in a digital economy by
enabling the private sector to create services that support greater choice for
consumers.” All of these are true if the alternative is a privately owned
digital currency or a payments system based on blockchain. But in effect we
already have a highly developed system of electronic money transfer in the
industrialised world based on existing currencies. Payment systems run by the
likes of Visa or Mastercard are already highly regulated and the various deposit
guarantee schemes in operation across Europe are sufficient to protect most
customers against bank default.
A counterargument is that the payments network is a critical
piece of the financial architecture where failure could prove catastrophic. The problems faced by Visa a couple of years ago,
when the payments system across Europe was knocked out for a number of hours,
demonstrated the risks inherent in the system. A CBDC could effectively act as
an alternative means of payment in the event of a more prolonged outage. But the
introduction of a CBDC would mean a significant amount of disruption to the
payments system, which would have to be redesigned. That would entail a lot of effort and cost for a mere
backup product.
It also raises a question of where the banking system fits
in. In the model proposed by the BoE, banks would be relegated to the role of Payment Interface Providers (PIPs) whose
role, amongst other things, is to “provide
a user‑friendly interface” to the
CBDC platform. But the very existence of banks could be threatened by the
introduction of a CBDC. Imagine that customers switch their deposits away from
their commercial bank to hold CBDC. Banks could lose low cost stable forms of
funding which would threaten their existence, to which they may respond by
raising interest rates to counter deposit outflows which in turn would destabilise asset portfolio decisions. In such a case banks would face the
potential threat of a huge contraction in their balance sheet, resulting in a
fire sale of assets as deposits disappear. As the BIS warned in a more sober paper than that produced by the BoE,
the role of banks in providing financial maturity transformation services is “not
clear.” Indeed, far from enhancing the stability of the financial system, a
CBDC that competes with existing financial institutions could amplify instability
if solvency/stability concerns at times of stress prompt a switch away from bank
deposits towards the CBDC.
In my view, there are a lot more questions than answers
regarding the introduction of CBDC. It is hard to avoid the sense that the
debate is at least partly fuelled by the fact that this is a fashionable topic driven by the declining use of physical cash. Moreover, significant technological advances mean that things are now possible which once
lay only in the realms of science fiction, and as I noted of blockchain back in 2017 it may be that this particular aspect of the digital currency debate is simply a solution looking for a problem to solve.
But there is also the possibility that in a world where interest rates are low, and likely to remain so for a long time to come, a CBDC would give central banks more control over the monetary policy transmission mechanism if they can persuade the private sector to give up cash. After all, you cannot impose a negative interest rate on cash because you can simply store it under the mattress, but the interest rate on digital deposits at the central bank could be tweaked at will. It could be that I am missing something but if central banks want us to swap existing financial products for a CBDC it strikes me that they have to make a much stronger case than they have up to now.