Looking at the issue in a longer-term context, the standard
approach in the academic literature is to point out that the neutral global
real interest rate has fallen over the past three decades. A Bank of England Working Paper published in December 2015 highlighted that the long-term risk free real rate has fallen by around 450 bps
in both emerging and developed economies since the 1980s.
The major factors which drive underlying long-term rates are
expectations of trend growth and factors which impact on savings and investment
preferences. The authors (Rachel and Smith) point out that the impact of a
growth slowdown on lower rates is limited, accounting for less than a quarter
of the total observed amount, and that the bulk of this can be attributed to
changes in savings and investment preferences. Their key finding is that whilst
there has been a sharp rise in saving preferences across the globe, desired
investment levels have also fallen significantly. This is, of course, fully
consistent with the savings glut hypothesis first postulated by Ben Bernanke in
2005. But Rachel and Smith go further by giving some quantitative estimates for
the magnitudes of the quantities involved. Thus, they attribute 100 of the 450 bps
decline in real rates to slower global growth; 90 bps to demographic factors
and 70 bps to lower investment demand. All told, once they account for a number
of other factors, they claim to account for 400 bps of the decline in real
rates.
As an academic tour de force, this paper is an excellent and
comprehensive overview of the factors driving rates lower. But it is not the
whole story. A quick look at the data, compiled by King and Low in 2014 (chart),
suggests that whilst there was indeed a sharp decline in the global real rate
between 1990 and 2008 of around 250 bps, the last 200 bps has occurred
post-financial crisis – a period when central banks slashed the short end of
the curve to zero at the same time as they were engaged in huge asset
purchases. In order to probe a little deeper, it is worth highlighting the
concept of the natural rate of interest, postulated by Swedish economist Knut
Wicksell at the end of the 19th century. Wicksell argued that if the
market rate exceeded the natural rate, prices would fall; if it fell below,
prices would rise. Obviously, we do not know what the natural rate is but a
quick-and-dirty method is to measure the difference between nominal GDP growth
and the interest rate to assess the extent to which the real and financial
sectors of the economy are misaligned.
In the UK, over the period 1975 to 2007, nominal GDP growth
was on average within 30 bps of Bank Rate but since 2010 it has averaged a full
300 bps above, and similar deviations have been recorded in the US and the euro
zone. This is not proof that interest rates are too low. After all, it is not
as if price inflation is a problem for the global economy. But it does highlight the
extent to which the interest rate on financial assets is too low relative to returns
on real assets, which in turn has helped to propel financial asset prices to stratospheric
levels. The concern is clearly that at some point asset markets will turn. But central
banks will probably have no choice but to watch the bubble deflate because
after having used a huge amount of monetary resources to pump markets up, they
cannot realistically deploy more to cushion the fall.
Whilst I understand why central banks have been reluctant to
raise interest rates so far – although the Fed is now grasping the nettle – I
do detect a slight note of complacency. The fact that (some) central bankers have justified their
low interest rate policy on the basis of lower global equilibrium rates, without
fully accounting for the fact that their actions have themselves pushed global
rates down, strikes me as distorted logic. I am reminded of the situation a decade
ago when many central bankers dismissed rapid growth in monetary aggregates as a problem
not worth worrying about, when in fact it reflected the actions of banks to
pump up their balance sheets. And we all know how that ended.