Thursday, 22 December 2016

Called to account

Whilst most of us are thinking about winding down for Christmas, the UK Treasury Select Committee today decided to play Scrooge by announcing that it will hold an inquiry in 2017 into the effectiveness and impact of post-2008 monetary policy in the UK. If the timing was a surprise, then the idea of opening up the conduct of monetary policy to this kind of scrutiny certainly is. Since the BoE was granted operational independence almost twenty years ago, I cannot recall an inquiry into monetary policy on these terms.

The TSC wishes to look more closely at three aspects of policy: (i) The effectiveness of monetary policy in meeting the inflation target; (ii) The unintended consequences of policy and (iii) monetary policy prospects. All of these topics have been covered on this blog at some time or another and the issues at stake here are not simply confined to the UK. The BIS has long pointed out that monetary policy has been kept too lax for too long, and that it indeed has pushed up financial asset prices with at best a questionable impact on the real economy. Of course, the issue is not whether so-called unconventional monetary policy was the right thing to do in 2009: It is whether it is still appropriate in 2016. Indeed, the BIS titled Chapter 1 of its 2015 Annual Report “Is the unthinkable becoming routine?”

I must confess to a couple of contradictory views on the question of whether monetary policy should become politicised in this way. On the one hand, although the BoE does have operational independence it is only right that it is subject to parliamentary account. After all, the decisions which it takes affect those to whom parliament is accountable: the electorate. Yet the BoE Governor and members of the MPC appear before the TSC at least four times per year, and in the course of 2016 Mark Carney has had to endure additional sessions where he has been forced to defend at length the BoE’s conduct both before and after the EU referendum. On the other hand, it is surely no coincidence that the pressure on the BoE has mounted after it in effect backed the losing side in the Brexit debate. I wrote before the EU referendum that in the event of a vote for Brexit “Mr Carney’s position will become extremely uncomfortable given the strained relationships between himself and many Eurosceptic MPs, some of whom sit on the Treasury Select Committee to which he is accountable.”

TSC Chairman Andrew Tyrie also pointed out that “the BoE has been given huge powers but that comes with equally large responsibilities” and in exchange for BoE autonomy, the governor should stick “closely to his statutory objectives.” This follows interventions by the BoE on issues such as the Scottish referendum (although senior civil servants at the Treasury were equally culpable for opining on that issue), climate change, inequality and pensions. The question of whether BoE officials – of which the governor is the most high profile – should be given the freedom to discuss other areas outside their direct remit is contentious. The likes of Tony Yates, professor of economics at Birmingham University and a long-established blogger, has often made the point that the governor should tread carefully. As he wrote earlier this month (here) “reflecting on how to respond to [the risks of social dysfunction] is just not a job the Bank has been mandated to carry out. At least not in public.”

This is fair comment. But as I have long argued, governments are not exactly rushing to fill the gap with policy prescriptions of their own and there is a role for policy heavyweights to speak out. After all the ECB has been doing it for years, and Alan Greenspan was never short of an opinion on policy matters outside the monetary sphere. In any case, many of these issues – notably fiscal policy – do impact elsewhere because they have a bearing on the appropriate monetary policy stance. But it is hard to avoid the suspicion that the decision to scrutinise the BoE’s policy remit is at least in part a response to Carney’s speech earlier this month, in which he called for a greater contribution from fiscal and structural policy to help support growth (here).

Two final thoughts: Given the limited resources available and a pressing time constraint, surely it would make more sense to focus on the policy response to Brexit in 2017 rather than waste energy on this issue. And second, by piling ever more scrutiny on monetary policymakers, the BoE’s policy independence will, at the margin, be eroded. After all, who is going to want to take unpopular decisions if they are going to be put under the microscope at every turn? Like a Facebook relationship status, monetary policy decision-making might be about to become very complicated.

Sunday, 18 December 2016

Globalisation: The good and the bad

Around fifteen years ago I was asked by the late Ulric Spencer to review a book for the Society of Business Economists  journal. The book in question was entitled “Localization:A Global Manifesto” by Colin Hines, a former head of economics at Greenpeace. I am rather afraid to say that when I first read the book in 2001, I did not particularly enjoy it and summed it up thus: “ultimately, it is difficult to escape the feeling that the book is a diatribe against the evils of capitalism.” But in the spirit of intellectual flexibility based on empirical observation, I may have been too hasty in my dismissal of some of Hines’ observations.

The basic premise of the book is that the global economic order “must reduce inequality, improve the basic provision of needs and adequately protect the environment.” There is nothing wrong with that, of course, but Hines’ proposed solution is a process of localisation in which policy actively discriminates in favour of the local. It is essentially the polar opposite of globalisation and can (in his view) be brought about by imposing restrictions on global capital flows and using the tax system to discriminate in favour of local interests.

I still think that his economic analysis is naïve and that it is essentially a late-twentieth century first world view of global problems. Nor am I sure that many people in less developed countries would thank Hines: After all, World Bank data suggest that poverty rates (defined as those living on less than $1.90 per day) have fallen from 42% of the world population in 1981 to below 11% by 2013. It is notable, too, that the book was written before China became the global powerhouse which it is today. Arguably, China has used elements of this localisation strategy to benefit the local economy. For example, many of the mighty western multinationals which Hines criticises have been forced to transfer their technology to local Chinese partners in order to be able to conduct business in the Middle Kingdom. Indeed, China has perhaps conducted the biggest poverty reduction policy of all time precisely thanks to globalisation, which has boosted incomes based on exports.

But where Hines’s views may carry more weight is in the process he described which might lead to a pushback against globalisation. In his words, “global deflation is being driven by relocation to cheaper labour countries, automation and public spending cuts.” This in turn results in significant under-utilisation of labour resources in western economies. He could well have foreshadowed the process which has led to the upsurge in anti-establishment political movements in recent years. There is more than an echo of Donald Trump in his assessment that the rolling back of the state has led to a vacuum which has been filled by multinational corporations, which have usurped government’s role in many areas of policymaking.

Part of the Brexit campaign’s appeal was to idealise a version of Britain as a powerhouse of world output, which was wiped out by government’s willingness to sell out the UK’s interests to the EU. I have a different take on it: The anger manifest during the Brexit campaign was partly the result of the failure by successive governments to promote local interests, at a time when the threat posed by globalisation did indeed mean that a lot of British jobs were exported to lower cost locations (a view echoed in the US election campaign). This was given full expression in the immigration debate. But as Beatrice Weder di Mauro points out (here), German immigration numbers are roughly similar to those of the UK. Yet the degree of anger in Germany towards the EU is a lot lower than in the UK. You might conclude from this that the real problem in the UK is not so much the EU, or immigration, but general dissatisfaction with the economic status quo - a view which is increasingly the consensus.

But although Hines appears to have correctly identified the process triggering the backlash, this does not mean that his solutions are necessarily the right ones. Localisation essentially places limits on trade but all economists would agree that trade does lead to higher living standards, although as BoE Governor Carney noted recently, “the benefits from trade are unequally spread across individuals and time.” Hines may be wrong to simply dismiss “the flawed theory of comparative advantage” but he is right in that much greater emphasis must be placed on the negative consequences. The events of 2016 should act as a wakeup call for western governments to look more closely at their policy prescriptions. This does not mean that protectionism is the answer, but it does mean a rethink of a policy which allows markets to provide unfettered solutions may be in order.

Thursday, 15 December 2016

Fail to prepare and prepare to fail


I was heartened this week to read the article in The Times by veteran (I hope he will forgive me for saying so) commentator David Smith in which he defended the role of economic forecasters (here). As he pointed out, forecasts may be wrong – indeed, they often are – but they need to be made. In my view, the trick is to know how to present the central case as one outcome amongst many possible paths, rather than focus solely on the one deemed to be the most likely.

This is a critical point. Indeed, part of the frustration which economists have is that their forecasts are often misrepresented. We know we don’t know precisely what the future holds and we are more than happy to say so – it’s just that quite often, that is not what people want to hear (I refer you to my post from July, here). Frequently, economic forecasts are treated with a reverence which they do not deserve. Indeed, this takes us to the heart of one of the subjects I have written about extensively on this blog: The criticisms levelled at some areas of macroeconomics and the degree of attention which we should pay to the work of economic practitioners. They are two different issues and we must be careful not to mix them up.

Whilst I admire the intellectual content of a lot of academic work, my criticism is that it too much of it is arcane and tries to dress up simple analysis in abstract mathematical terms. Practitioners tend to eschew the overly complicated – not because we don’t understand it (though sometimes that might be the case), but partly because we operate under greater time and resource constraints which mean that our analysis falls short of the standards which academics set for themselves. Most of us do have an understanding of the academic material but choose which parts we can use and which parts we can afford to ignore.

But the criticism of economics by outsiders is different. They argue that because we get things wrong, our forecasts are not to be trusted. And that is why (to quote Michal Gove) "we've all had enough of experts." I thus took great exception to an argument used by the FT journalist Wolfgang Munchau who suggested that "Because of a tendency to exaggerate, macroeconomists are no longer considered experts on the macroeconomy." Let's just stop and think about this. Exaggerate what exactly? The pre-Brexit exaggeration came from politicians (George Osborne in particular) who blew up work by the likes of the Treasury to imply it said something it did not. The analysis said that UK output would be anywhere between 4% and 7.5% below that which would otherwise result if we stayed in the EU, over a 15 year horizon. That is a significant welfare loss, but it probably means that the UK would grow at around the same rate as the euro zone rather than what we have experienced here in recent years.

The press is not immune from the tendency to exaggerate. Economists are routinely described as "experts" and forecasts treated with undue reverence – until they turn out to be wrong and are dismissed with Gove-like contempt. Indeed, this term "expert" appears to have a recent provenance and I don't remember being described as such until relatively recently. As a case in point, consider this quote from The Observer suggesting that "Ongoing uncertainty over the manner of the UK’s departure from the EU is likely to weigh down the property market in 2017, say experts, who predict little or no growth in prices amid a slowdown in sales." (here). It is more accurate to say that those who work in the property industry have given an educated guess, based on their experience and knowledge, of what they expect to happen. It’s not as sexy as being an expert but it’s closer to the truth.

Whilst I have done my fair share of forecasting over the years – some of which was accurate, a lot of which was not – we have to recognise that economics is not a predictive discipline. Economists have no better idea than the next person what will happen next week or next year. But what we can do is put issues into context, based on past experience, and we try to offer an evidence-based view of what might happen in future. That does not guarantee we will be right. But as director of the NIESR, Jagjit Chadha, has pointed out “It is quite obvious that we cannot know the future. But it is equally obvious that we cannot afford not to think and plan for the future.” In other words, fail to prepare and prepare to fail.


Tuesday, 13 December 2016

Think healthy

The journalist AA Gill died at the weekend after a short battle with cancer. His final article was published posthumously in the most recent issue of The Sunday Times, describing how he coped with his fatal illness. What was particularly striking about the article (the gist of which you can get from the BBC here or The Guardian here) is the description of how cancer survival rates in the UK are the lowest in western Europe. The doctor who treated him noted that the reasons for such a poor performance are due to “the nature of the health service” which imposes such a huge administrative burden that it hampers early diagnosis of the disease which is so vital to successful treatment.

Many foreign people of my acquaintance do not share the same reverence which the Brits show for the National Health Service. This is in no way to denigrate the professionalism of those who work in it. The doctors, nurses and all other medical staff do a wonderful job saving lives and healing the sick – but they work in a system which is dysfunctional, as many NHS employees readily admit. As Gill himself noted, the Brits lie to themselves about the quality of the service they receive. “We say it’s the envy of the world. It isn’t. We say there’s nothing else like it. There is. We say it’s the best in the West. It’s not. We think it’s the cheapest. It isn’t … You will live longer in France and Germany, get treated faster and more comfortably in Scandinavia.”

When it was founded in 1948, it offered a genuinely revolutionary approach to health provision in the west. But precisely because it is free at the point of consumption, it has always struggled with questions of “how best to organise and manage the service, how to fund it adequately, how to balance the often conflicting demands and expectations of patients, staff and taxpayer [and] how to ensure finite resources are targeted where they are most needed.” (source: Geoffrey Rivett, here). As treatment becomes more expensive and the population gets older the pressure on resources becomes more intense. The current government has opted to ring-fence NHS spending (but not welfare spending – we’ll do that another day) but continues to struggle to reform the system. No politician has yet had the courage to impose charges as a means of regulating near-infinite demand, such is the totemic importance of the NHS to the British electorate.

Precisely because resources are finite, Gill was denied treatment on the NHS which may well have prolonged his life because it was deemed too expensive. The cost of providing him with a drug called Nivomulab would have amounted to between £60k and £100k per year – four times the cost of traditional chemotherapy. And this is where economics comes in. Health economists are employed in the NHS to ensure that best use is made of the resources available. It is a job which needs to be done. After all, if economics is (at least partially) about the study of the allocation of scarce resources, then health issues would appear to be highly amenable to the scrutiny of economists.

But Johannes Bircher at the University of Bern argues that we do not actually know what health is (here) and therefore it is not a commodity which can be priced: After all, we cannot produce, obtain, exchange, sell or store it. Such an approach rather undermines the assumptions underlying Kenneth Arrow’s classic 1963 paper (here) which treats health as a commodity – albeit one with different characteristics to normal consumer goods.

My own issue with the field of health economics stems back to my undergraduate days and questions of cost-benefit analysis, because I have always struggled with the question of how you put a price on life. No matter what form of valuation you use, no amount of money can ever compensate for the very essence of being. This is not a question for economists – it is one for the philosophers. 

All that aside, Gill showed a remarkable degree of stoicism in facing up to his fate and wrote that he was happy for the last 30 years of life, having broken his alcohol dependency cycle in the mid-1980s. For a man who wrote so wittily and so scathingly on a range of subjects, it is only fitting that we leave the last word to him on a subject we all know and love so well – Brexit. “We all know what ‘getting our country back’ means. It’s snorting a line of the most pernicious and debilitating Little English drug, nostalgia. The warm, crumbly, honey-coloured, collective “yesterday” with its fond belief that everything was better back then, that Britain (England, really) is a worse place now than it was at some foggy point in the past where we achieved peak Blighty.

Saturday, 10 December 2016

The beatings will continue until morale improves

The ECB’s decision to extend its asset purchases beyond next March, albeit at a slower pace, is seen in some quarters as a tapering announcement and is viewed by others as a further round of monetary easing. To recap, the ECB announced that it will extend its asset purchases to December 2017, rather than end in March, but at a rate of €60bn per month rather than the current pace of €80bn. Technically, a reduced pace of asset purchases is a form of tapering. But let us not forget that when the ECB began its purchases last year, it was initially buying at a monthly rate of €60bn. I am inclined to view the announcement this week as continued monetary expansion rather than a precursor of tapering.

Looking more closely at the statement issued by the ECB (here) the presumption is that it will have to do more rather than less. Purchases will continue to December 2017 “or beyond, if necessary” and “if … the outlook becomes less favourable … the Governing Council intends to increase the programme in terms of size and/or duration.” Nowhere does it say that the central bank will scale back purchases if the outlook improves or if inflation picks up more quickly than anticipated. In that sense, it is an asymmetric commitment.

Increasingly, I get the sense that the ECB is out of step. It came late to the QE party, beginning asset purchases only in 2015 whereas the Fed and BoE started in 2009. The Fed has long since ended its asset purchase programme, and the BoE announced only a modest expansion in August in the wake of the EU referendum, having been on hold for much of the preceding four years. There is also clear evidence that the bang for the buck (or euro) diminishes the more QE is undertaken. Indeed, the BIS made precisely this point in its 2016 Annual Report (here, see p72). As it pointed out, “there are natural limits … to how far interest rates can be pushed into negative territory, central bank balance sheets expanded, spreads compressed and asset prices boosted. And there are limits to how far spending can be brought forward from the future. As these limits are approached, the marginal effect of policy tends to decline, and any side effects – whether strictly economic or of a political economy nature – tend to rise.

The problem is not all of the ECB’s doing. Successive Presidents have been making the point since the ECB’s inception in 1999 that governments need to do more to reform their economies. And they simply have not done so. This mirrors comments by BoE Governor Carney who made a similar point regarding the UK (as I noted here). But the need for reform is far more acute in the euro zone. In a fixed exchange rate system, the burden of adjustment for economic problems falls squarely on the domestic labour market; No longer can countries rely on a weaker exchange rate to bail them out. Italy is a case in point, where the economy has barely grown in the last 16 years, and where politicians have been frustrated in their efforts to reform the domestic economy by groups with a vested interest in preserving the status quo (notably the unions). Whilst you have to feel a bit sorry for well-meaning politicians such as Matteo Renzi, it is hardly a surprise when electorates turn on their politicians as the Italians did last weekend in the constitutional reform referendum.

However, there is growing concern in Germany that the euro zone is morphing into a transfer union, as surplus countries continue to prop up the ailing southern peripherals. Technically, this is true. But this is also a necessary condition for the euro zone to survive. Not all countries can run external surpluses, and they certainly cannot all run surpluses against each other. In the absence of these transfers, the euro zone is just another fixed currency regime which will inevitably fall apart. Suggestions last week from German Finance Minister Wolfgang Schäuble that Greece must carry out structural reforms instead of receiving debt relief are to entirely miss the point about the nature of the problems which it faces. Greece is labouring under such a huge debt burden (182% of GDP) that unless part of it is written off, it will simply default. Period! And most people know it.

ECB President Draghi may be pilloried for running a policy which appears to benefit “profligate” southern European countries, but he is stepping into the void created by politicians who are not doing anything to support the economy via fiscal policy or structural reform. Without his efforts, the euro zone would be in an even sorrier state. But as the BIS analysis suggests, economies cannot live on monetary policy alone. And all this does raise genuine existential concerns for the future of the euro zone. We used to talk of Grexit long before we had even heard of Brexit but all the problems which the region has dealt with in the last seven years are still there. The beatings will continue until morale improves.

Thursday, 8 December 2016

Those sixties weren't so great


Bank of England Governor Carney delivered an interesting speech this week (here) in which he took a closer look at the reasons behind the rise in populist responses to our current economic ills. None of it was particularly new, but it was illuminating for the fact that a heavyweight economic policymaker addressed the issues in a more rational fashion than I have yet heard from most politicians.

Most of the newspaper headlines focused on his one killer statistic that in the UK we are currently experiencing “the first lost decade since the 1860s.” (Clearly those sixties were not all about flower power). Carney used the excellent BoE database (here) to show that real wages over the last ten years have grown at their slowest rate since the mid-nineteenth century. And as I have long argued, although productivity performance has been lousy it has at least outstripped real wage growth, which suggests that workers have not been compensated for their efforts. Indeed, the share of wage and salary income in UK GDP (technically, gross valued added at factor cost, but let’s not overcomplicate things) has fallen from around 58% in 2011 to 56.5% in 2015.

Carney makes the valid point that although economists are unshakeable in their belief that society benefits from free trade, not everybody benefits equally. As he put it, “the benefits from trade are unequally spread across individuals and time.” So far as I am concerned, he is preaching to the converted: Those of us who recall the wholesale destruction of large parts of the UK manufacturing base in the 1980s need no reminding that there were significant adjustment costs as those losing their jobs had nowhere else to turn. Some people were eventually forced to relocate to find work; others had to wait for new local opportunities to arise. Viewed from 30 years on, many of the economic scars have healed as the UK macroeconomic data show that real incomes per head are almost double the levels of the early-1980s. But at the time the local dislocation was huge, and today it is not just the UK which is facing these problems: It is an issue across the whole of (what is still euphemistically called) the industrialised world.

Those who argue that markets will always adjust often overlook the fact that the longer-term gains are smaller than they appear when offset against the short-term costs. The pace of technological change magnifies these impacts. If people are concerned that their jobs can be replaced by machines, they are bound to become fearful and resentful. This is, of course, not new as the Luddite movement of the early 19th century demonstrates (here for a quick overview). We should also take encouragement from the fact that societies have usually managed to accommodate technological advances relatively easily. But this will not happen if we continue to plod down the same unimaginative policy path that we have been following in recent decades.

Before turning to what needs to be done, Carney defended the role of monetary policy by arguing that it “has offset all of the headwinds to growth arising from private deleveraging, fiscal consolidation and subdued world growth.  People haven’t been made poorer.” But he noted that they feel worse off because productivity growth remains subdued. Recall Paul Krugman’s line that “productivity isn’t everything, but in the long run it is almost everything.  A country’s ability to improve its standard of living over time depends almost entirely on its ability to raise its output per worker.” (Actually that is true only if workers are compensated for their productivity performance which, at least in the UK, has not been true in recent years).

Carney thus believes that efforts to boost productivity are an important element in generating an economic turnaround. Quite how we achieve this is not so easy to identify and we will revisit it another time. However, his conclusion was a sharp retort to the recent criticisms which have been put his way by politicians: “To address the deeper causes of weak growth, higher inequality and rising insecurity requires a globalisation that works for all. For the societies of free-trading, networked countries to prosper, they must first re-distribute some of the gains from trade and technology, and then re-skill and reconnect all of their citizens. By doing so, they can put individuals back in control.” This is an interesting twist on the take-back-control of the Brexiteers, and I have to say I agree with the Governor on this one.

It is just a pity that such a cogent analysis of the UK’s ills was left until almost six months after the referendum. But when it takes the Governor of the Bank of England to point out that “we must grow our economy by rebalancing the mix of monetary policy, fiscal policy and structural reform,” this strikes me as a sad indictment of a political class which continues to deflect the blame for years of policy neglect onto the EU.

Saturday, 3 December 2016

Better not call Paul

Paul Samuelson was quite clearly a brilliant man and one of the most influential economists of the twentieth century. His magnum opus, Foundations of Economic Analysis published in 1947, was one of the first rigorous mathematical treatments of important economic concepts. But for all its undoubted brilliance, I have long thought that Samuelson's work was one of the worst things to happen to economics.

This is not to denigrate his work. Samuelson produced some original insight in fields as diverse as consumer theory, welfare economics, public finance and international trade issues. Rather the problem is that he spawned a number of imitators who, captivated by the elegance of his work, attempted to replicate his mathematics rather than his economic insights with the result that academic economics became ever more algebraically rigorous. As Lo and Mueller (2010, here) have pointed out, whilst economics has become much more rigorous and "has led to a number of important breakthroughs ...  ‘physics envy’ has also created a false sense of mathematical precision".

This level of abstraction was part of the reason why the severity of the market crash of 2008 came as such a surprise. As Goldman Sachs' CFO commented in the Financial Times in August 2007 "We are seeing things that were 25-standard deviation moves, several days in a row." Andy Haldane, the Bank of England's chief economist, later pointed out: "Assuming a normal distribution, a 7.26-sigma daily loss would be expected to occur once every 13.7 billion or so years. That is roughly the estimated age of the universe. A 25-sigma event would be expected to occur once every 6x10124 lives of the universe. That is quite a lot of human histories." In simple terms, the risk models used at the time were using the wrong statistical distribution to model risk and making firm conclusions based upon it.

It is thus no surprise that attempts have been made to reclaim the centre ground of economics. A recently-published book entitled Econocracy: The Perils of Leaving Economics to the Experts (here), attempts to redress the balance. As the authors note: “Politics and policymaking are conducted in the language of economics and economic logic shapes how political issues are thought about and addressed. The result is that the majority of citizens, who cannot speak this language, are locked out of politics while political decisions are increasingly devolved to experts.”

A letter in the Financial Times (here) recently made a similar point, arguing that "the folly of mainstream economists is their pretence to emulate the natural sciences, presuming to be value free." The author, Yeomin Yoon of Seton Hall University in New Jersey, noted that current practice increasingly deviates from the teachings of Alfred Marshall, who argued: “(1) Use mathematics as a shorthand language, rather than as an engine of inquiry. (2) Keep to them till you have done. (3) Translate into English. (4) Then illustrate by examples that are important in real life. (5) Burn the mathematics. (6) If you can’t succeed in 4, burn 3 … I think you should do all you can to prevent people from using mathematics in cases in which the English language is as short as the mathematical.” Given that Marshall was no mean mathematician himself that is a pretty powerful argument.

Whilst it is easy to be critical of academic economics for creating a level of abstraction that so many people feel unable to relate to, and as a consequence feel able to ignore (as we saw during the Brexit discussions), the future may not be so bleak. Macroeconomics may be operating in an intellectual cul-de-sac (said the macroeconomist) but matters are not helped by the fact that too many people outside the profession expect economists to be able to predict the future with an unreasonable degree of accuracy. Rather than the study of abstract macroeconomic quantities with highly politicised connotations, the roots of economics lie in the study of how people make decisions. As a result, the discipline of microeconomics is thriving. The new and exciting field is behavioural economics where experimentation rather than algebra is used to tease out some of the newest ideas in economic thinking.

Economics is a discipline which has traditionally borrowed ideas from other areas. For a long time, perhaps, it borrowed too much from mathematics and the physical sciences, but by going back to its roots as a social science and borrowing ideas from psychology, the revolution which so many people are calling for may actually already be happening.