One of the key premises of the paper is that unilateral abolition of all UK tariffs should be a key plank of the post-Brexit world. But most economists do not buy the analysis. For one thing, it assumes that most of the benefits to the UK are derived from the import side. In the view of EfFT, there will be an immediate increase in UK living standards as a result of the abolition of UK import tariffs. This will put competitive pressure on domestic business to improve its relative position and as a result the economy will emerge stronger in the long-term. Minford et al justify this with reference to the example of Sir Robert Peel’s abolition of the Corn Laws in 1846 which “greatly reduc[ed] the price of food and help[ed] to stimulate the industrial revolution.”
There are just a few tiny problems with this Panglossian view of the world.
- First, it will lead to a massive initial widening of the trade deficit which will likely result in a sterling depreciation which boosts inflation and squeezes household incomes – a bit like we are seeing today.
- Second, it will wipe out large chunks of UK manufacturing industry which are unable to compete with low cost Asian producers. Even if there is a competitiveness response, it will take years to show through and we would have to balance out the short-term welfare losses against any potential long-term gains.
- Third, Minford argues that “to offset the long run effect of losing EU protection, manufacturing productivity needs to be raised, compared with no Brexit, by only about 1% a year for a decade, which looks entirely feasible.” Given that one of the main macroeconomic problems we face today is the weakness of productivity, which has flatlined since 2008, raising productivity growth to 4% per annum, as he implies, looks entirely infeasible.
- Fourth, the 1846 example is misguided. In a world of much more intense global competition, it is not clear that the UK could easily cope with the near-tripling of the trade deficit that occurred in 1847 and which was left permanently higher as a result.
Nor do most economists buy the view that unilateral tariff
elimination is a sensible strategy. If you don’t believe in unilateral nuclear
disarmament why should you believe the same principle applies to trade? You
might promise to cut tariffs during trade negotiations but you certainly do not
throw away one of the main bargaining chips before even entering the
negotiating chamber. He may be a good macroeconomist but he’s a lousy game
theorist.
Alan Winters, at the University of Sussex, has been a major
critic of Minford’s analysis all along and his latest blog piece does a good job of skewering some of the assumptions. The detailed breakdown of
the EfFT numbers suggests that the gains from free trade alone will amount to
4% of GDP. Winters points out “EfFT claim
that current EU trade barriers are equivalent to a tax of 20% on both
agriculture and manufacturing. In manufactures only about 3.5% of the extra
cost is tariffs, so what is the rest? If the 20% is correct, much of the
remaining 16%-17% is standards.” Applying the arithmetic, abolishing trade
barriers might only be expected to produce a boost equivalent to 0.7% of GDP
(4%*3.5%/20%).
Indeed, this hits upon a major problem – standards and other
non-tariff barriers are much bigger obstacles to trade. One simple example is
differing car pollution emission limits: Even if tariffs could
be eliminated, the fact that cars are subject to different standards around the
world significantly raises production costs. Indeed it was the raising of US
emissions standards in the 1970s which killed off the classic Jaguar E Type.
Another example is financial services, in which a passport allowing regulatory
equivalence enables banks to trade their products across EU borders without let
or hindrance. It may not be everyone’s idea of a great industrial role model
but the UK does at least run a consistent external surplus in financial
services trade.
Leaving the EU Single Market will require the UK to
massively raise its foreign trade with non-EU countries to make up for the loss
of tariff-free access to the EU market. Analysis by NIESR suggests that if the
UK left the single market but made unilateral trade deals with major developing
economies and the Anglosphere, it would only claw back about one-third of the
20-30% reduction in lost total trade resulting from leaving the EU. Moreover, deals
on services trade are far less comprehensive than those for goods, and as NIESR
has also indicated, it will be hard to replicate the EU deals that we have
now.
Winters also points out that “EfFT believe that we can get all the benefits of the European Single
Market (SM) unilaterally. That is not true. The SM boosts our exports, which
confers benefits over and above those achieved by liberalising imports.” It
is precisely because the UK has some say over single market regulations it can influence
them to benefit certain industries, such as financial services. Small
economies simply cannot decide their own trading standards in a globalised
world and the UK will become a rule taker rather than a rule maker. The bottom line
is that by leaving the single market, the UK will be giving up a lot of
influence over its ability to set terms and conditions. Far from taking back
control, we will be throwing ourselves on the mercy of the global economy.
One of the ironies associated with this analysis, which has been criticised for being given far too much prominence,
is that it is the mirror image of the doom-laden scenarios produced before the
referendum which were dismissed as Project Fear. So why should this be treated so
reverentially by the media? After all, it was produced by the “experts” we all
thought we had heard enough from.